American Economic Review 2014, 104(3): 753–792 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.3.753 Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidence from US Regions† By Emi Nakamura and Jón Steinsson* We use rich historical data on military procurement to estimate the effects of government spending. We exploit regional variation in military buildups to estimate an “open economy relative multiplier” of approximately 1.5. We develop a framework for interpreting this estimate and relating it to estimates of the standard closed economy aggregate multiplier. The latter is highly sensitive to how strongly aggregate monetary and tax policy “leans against the wind.” Our open economy relative multiplier “differences out” these effects because monetary and tax policies are uniform across the nation. Our evidence indicates that demand shocks can have large effects on output. (JEL E12, E32, E62, F33, H56, H57, R12)
The effect of government spending on output is often summarized by a multiplier—the percentage increase in output that results when government spending is increased by 1 percent of GDP. There is a wide range of views about this statistic in the literature. On the one hand, the recent American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA)—perhaps the largest fiscal stimulus plan in US history—was motivated by a relatively high estimate of the multiplier of 1.6 (Romer and Bernstein 2009). Other studies argue that the multiplier is substantially smaller and potentially close to zero. In particular, if the determination of output is dominated by supply-side factors, an increase in government purchases to a large extent “crowds out” private sector consumption and investment. The wide range of views on the multiplier arises in part from the difficulty of measuring it. Changes in government spending are rarely exogenous, leading to a range of estimates depending on the estimation approach.1 Two main approaches have been used to estimate the multiplier in the academic literature. The first is to study the output effects of increases in military spending associated with wars, which are plausibly unrelated to prevailing macroeconomic conditions (Ramey and Shapiro 1998; Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher 1999; Burnside, Eichenbaum,
* Nakamura: Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, 3022 Broadway, New York, NY 10027 (e-mail: enakamura@columbia.edu); Steinsson: Department of Economics, Columbia University, 420 W 118 St., New York, NY 10027 (e-mail: jsteinsson@columbia.edu). We thank Nicolas Crouzet, Shaowen Luo, and Thuy Lan Nguyen for excellent research assistance. We thank Steve Davis, Gauti Eggertsson, Jordi Galí, Erik Hurst, Karel Mertens, Marcelo Moreira, James Stock, Ivan Werning, Michael Woodford, Pierre Yared, Motohiro Yogo, and seminar participants at various institutions for helpful comments and conversations. † Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.3.753 to visit the article page for additional materials and author disclosure statement(s). 1 For surveys of the existing evidence, see, for example, Perotti (2008), Hall (2009), Alesina and Ardagna (2010), and Cogan et al. (2010). 753
754 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 and Fisher 2004; Ramey 2011; Barro and Redlick 2011; Fisher and Peters 2010). This approach faces the challenge that large wars are relatively infrequent. Another challenge is confounding variation associated with tax increases, price controls, patriotism, and other macroeconomic shocks.2 The second main approach used to identify the multiplier is the structural VAR approach (Blanchard and Perotti 2002; Perotti 2008; Mountford and Uhlig 2009; Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh 2013). This approach relies on structural assumptions about output and fiscal policy dynamics to estimate the multiplier. The wide range of views on the multiplier also arises from contrasting results in the theoretical literature. The government spending multiplier is not a deep structural parameter like the elasticity of labor supply or the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Different models, therefore, differ in their implications about the multiplier depending on what is assumed about preferences, technology, government policy, and various “frictions.” Simple versions of the Neoclassical model generally imply a small multiplier, typically smaller than 0.5 (see, e.g., Baxter and King 1993). The multiplier is sensitive to how the spending is financed—smaller if it is financed by distortionary taxes than lump sum taxes.3 In New Keynesian models, the size of the multiplier depends critically on the extent to which monetary policy “leans against the wind.” Strongly counter-cyclical monetary policy—such as that commonly estimated for the Volcker-Greenspan period—can generate quite low multipliers—comparable to those for the Neoclassical model. However, when monetary policy is less responsive—e.g., at the zero lower bound—the multiplier can exceed two.4 Clearly, there is no “single” government spending multiplier. This is likely one contributing factor for the wide range of empirical estimates of the multiplier discussed above, since different identification schemes implicitly put different weights on periods when different policy regimes were in place. We analyze the effects of government spending in a monetary and fiscal union— the United States. We estimate the effect that an increase in government spending in one region of the union relative to another has on relative output and employment. We refer to this as the “open economy relative multiplier.” We use variation in regional military procurement associated with aggregate military buildups and drawdowns to estimate these effects. The “open economy relative multiplier” we estimate differs conceptually from the more familiar “closed economy aggregate multiplier” that one might estimate using aggregate US data. At first glance, this might seem to be a pure disadvantage, since much interest is focused on the closed economy aggregate multiplier. We show, however, that the open economy relative multiplier has important advantages. These advantages stem from the fact that relative policy is precisely pinned down across regions in the United States: The Federal Reserve cannot raise interest rates in some states relative to others, and federal tax policy is common across states in the union.
2 Most of the evidence from this approach derives from the United States’ experience during WWII and the Korean War, when changes in US military spending were largest and most abrupt as a fraction of total output. Hall (2009) and Barro and Redlick (2011) emphasize that it is not possible to draw meaningful inference using aggregate data on military spending after 1955 because there is insufficient variation in military spending in this period. 3 See, e.g., Baxter and King (1993); Ohanian (1997); Corsetti, Meier, and Muller (2012); and Drautzburg and Uhlig (2011). 4 At the zero lower bound, fiscal stimulus lowers real interest rates by raising inflation (Eggertsson 2010; Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo 2011).
756 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 multiplier is thus akin to a closed economy aggregate multiplier for a more accommodative monetary policy than the one seen in the United States under Volcker and Greenspan. This implies that our estimate of 1.5 for the open economy relative multiplier is perfectly consistent with much lower existing estimates of the closed economy aggregate multiplier (e.g., those of Barro and Redlick 2011). Since the nominal interest rate is fixed across regions in our setting, one might think that our open economy relative multiplier would be akin to the closed economy aggregate multiplier when nominal interest rates are fixed at the zero lower bound, in which case the New Keynesian model generates large multipliers (Eggertsson 2010; Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo 2011). We show that this is not the case. This simple intuition ignores a crucial dynamic aspect of price responses in a monetary union. Since transitory demand shocks do not lead to permanent changes in relative prices across regions and the exchange rate is fixed within the monetary union, any increase in prices in the short run in one region relative to the other must eventually be reversed in the long run. This implies that even though relative short-term real interest rates fall in response to government spending shocks in our model, relative long-term real interest rates don’t (in contrast to the zero lower bound setting). It is the fall in long-term real interest rates that generates a high multiplier in the zero lower bound setting. The absence of such a fall in our setting explains why the open economy relative multiplier generated by the baseline New Keynesian model is much lower than the closed economy aggregate multiplier at the zero lower bound. The intuition for why the open economy relative multiplier is larger than the closed economy aggregate multiplier for normal monetary policy is similar to the intuition for why the government spending multiplier is larger under a fixed than a f lexible exchange rate in the Mundell-Fleming model. In fact, we show that the open economy relative multiplier is exactly the same as the aggregate multiplier in a small open economy with a fixed exchange rate. Our estimate can, therefore, be compared with other estimates of multipliers in open economies with fixed exchange rates. Based on data from 44 countries, Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Vegh (2013) estimate a multiplier of 1.5 for countries that operate a fixed exchange rate regime, but a much lower multiplier for countries operating a flexible exchange rate regime.7 An important difference between our open economy relative multiplier and the closed economy aggregate multiplier is that the regions that receive spending don’t have to pay for it. Could this perhaps explain the “large” relative multiplier we estimate? In this respect, it is important to keep in mind that in a Neoclassical model, an increase in wealth shifts labor supply in and thus reduces the multiplier. With sticky prices and home bias, an increase in wealth also increases aggregate demand for home goods, which acts to increase the multiplier. In our baseline model, we assume that financial markets are complete across regions. Thus any increase in wealth associated with the government spending is fully shared with the rest of the economy. Following Farhi and Werning (2012), we consider a version of our model in which f inancial markets are incomplete across regions. We use this model to compare the effects of federally financed government spending and locally financed government 7 Kraay (2012) estimates a government spending multiplier of about 0.5 for 29 aid-dependent developing countries using variation in World Bank lending.
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 757 spending. For our baseline parameters, the open economy relative multiplier is only slightly larger for federally financed spending than locally financed spending. The theoretical framework we describe helps to interpret recent and ongoing research on the effects of other forms of local government spending (Acconcia, Corsetti, and Simonelli 2011; Chodorow-Reich et al. 2012; Clemens and Miran 2012; Cohen, Coval, and Malloy 2011; Fishback and Kachanovskaya 2010; Serrato and Wingender 2010; Shoag 2010; Wilson 2012). In general, these studies appear to estimate open economy relative multipliers of a similar magnitude as we do. There are, however, a few potentially important differences between our study and these. Some of these studies focus on windfall transfers rather than purchases.8 One advantage of our focus on military purchases is that it seems reasonable to assume that they are separable from other forms of consumption, as is typically assumed in macroeconomic models. Our empirical approach builds on previous work by Davis, Loungani, and Mahidhara (1997), who study several drivers of regional economic fluctuations, including military procurement.9 Several other studies on the impact of regional defense spending are surveyed in Braddon (1995). The most important difference in our empirical methodology relative to these studies is our use of variation in aggregate military spending in creating instruments to account for potential endogeneity of local procurement spending as well as measurement error. Our work is also related to Canova and Pappa (2007), who study the price effects of fiscal shocks in a monetary union. Our theoretical analysis is related to earlier work on monetary and fiscal policy in a monetary union by Benigno and Benigno (2003) and Galí and Monacelli (2008). The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section I describes the data we use. Section II presents our empirical results. Section III presents the model we use to interpret these empirical results. Section IV presents our theoretical results. Section V concludes. I. Data Relative to other forms of federal government spending, the geographical distribution of military spending is remarkably well documented, perhaps because of the intense political scrutiny surrounding these purchases. Our main source for military spending data is the electronic database of DD-350 military procurement forms available from the US Department of Defense. These forms document military purchases of everything from repairs of military facilities to the purchase of aircraft carriers. They cover purchases greater than $10,000 up to 1983 and greater than
8 Our open economy relative multiplier is not a “windfall” or “manna from heaven” multiplier. Rather, the spending we study is akin to a foreign demand shock. Agents are getting paid to produce goods that are “exported” for use in defense of the union as a whole. 9 Similarly, Hooker and Knetter (1997) estimate the effects of military procurement on subsequent employment growth using a somewhat different specification.
758 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 $25,000 thereafter.10 These data are for the federal government fiscal year.11 We have used the DD-350 database to compile data on total military procurement by state and year for 1966 –2006.12 The DD-350 forms list prime contractors and provide information on the location where the majority of the work was performed. An important concern is the extent of interstate subcontracting. To help assess the extent of such subcontracting, we have compiled a new dataset on shipments to the government from defense oriented industries. The source of these data are the Annual Survey of Shipments by DefenseOriented Industries conducted by the US Census Bureau from 1963 through 1983 (Census Bureau 1963–1983). In Section IIB, we compare variation in procurement spending with these shipments data. Our primary measure of state output is the GDP by state measure constructed by the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), which is available since 1963. We also make use of analogous data by major SIC/NAICS grouping.13 We use the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) payroll survey from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) program to measure state-level employment. We also present results for the BEA measure of state employment which is available since 1969. We obtain state population data from the Census Bureau.14 We obtain data on oil prices (the annual average spot price of West Texas Intermediate) and the Federal Funds rate (annual average) from the St. Louis Federal Reserve’s FRED database. Finally, to analyze price effects, we construct state and regional inflation measures from several sources. Before 1995, we rely on state-level inflation series constructed by Del Negro (1998a, b) for the period 1969–1995 using a combination of BLS regional inflation data and cost of living estimates from the American Chamber of Commerce Realtors Association (ACCRA).15 After 1995, we construct state-level price indexes by multiplying a population-weighted average of cost of living indexes from the ACCRA for each region with the US aggregate Consumer Price Index. Reliable annual consumption data are, unfortunately, not available at the state level for most of the time period or regions we consider.16 10 Purchases reported on DD-350 forms account for 90 percent of military purchases. DD-1057 forms are used to summarize smaller transactions but do not give the identity of individual sellers. Our analysis of census shipment data in Section II suggests DD-350 purchases account for almost all of the time-series variation in total military procurement. 11 Since 1976, this has been from October 1 to September 30. Prior to 1976, it was from July 1 to June 30. 12 The electronic military prime contract data file was created in the mid-1960s and records individual military prime contracts since 1966. This occurred around the time Robert McNamara was making sweeping changes to the procurement process of the US Department of Defense. Aggregate statistics before this point do not appear to be a reliable source of information on military purchases since large discrepancies arise between actual outlays and procurement for the earlier period, particularly at the time of the Korean War. See the Department of Defense Greenbook for aggregate historical series of procurement and outlays. 13 The data are organized by SIC code before 1997 and NAICS code after 1997. The BEA publishes the data for both systems in 1997, allowing the growth rate series to be smoothly pasted together. 14 Between census years, population is estimated using a variety of administrative data sources including birth and death records, IRS data, Medicare data, and data from the Department of Defense. Since 1970, we are also able to obtain population by age group, which allows us to construct estimates of the working age population. 15 See Appendix A of Del Negro (1998a) for the details of this procedure. 16 Retail sales estimates from Sales and Marketing Management Survey of Buying Power have sometimes been used as a proxy for state-level annual consumption. However, these data are constructed by using employment data to impute retail sales between census years, rendering them inappropriate for our purposes. Fishback, Horrace, and Kantor (2005) study the longer run effects of New Deal spending on retail sales using census data.
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 759 II. Measurement of the Open Economy Relative Multiplier A. Empirical Specification and Identification We use variation in military procurement spending across states and regions to identify the effects of government spending on output. Our empirical specification is (1) Y it − Y it−2 _ Y it−2 = α i + γ t + β G it − G it−2 _ Y it−2 + ε it, where Y it is per capita output in region i in year t, G it is per capita military procurement spending in region i in year t, and α i and γ t represent state and year f ixed effects.17 The inclusion of state fixed effects implies that we are allowing for state specific time trends in output and military procurement spending. The inclusion of time fixed effects allows us to control for aggregate shocks and aggregate policy—such as changes in distortionary taxes and aggregate monetary policy. All variables in the regression are measured in per capita terms.18 We regress two-year changes in output on two-year changes in spending, as a crude way of capturing dynamics in the relationship between government spending and output.19 We use annual panel data on state and regional output and spending for 1966 –2006 and account for the overlapping nature of the observations in our regression by clustering the standard errors by state or region. The regional data are constructed by aggregating state-level data within census divisions. We make one adjustment to the census divisions. This is to divide the “South Atlantic” division into two parts because of its large size.20 This yields ten regions made up of contiguous states. Our interest focuses on the coefficient β in regression (1), which we refer to as the “open economy relative multiplier.” An important challenge to identifying the effect of government spending is that government spending is potentially endogenous since military spending is notoriously political.21 We, therefore, estimate equation (1) using an instrumental variables approach. Our instruments are based on two characteristics of the evolution of military spending. Figure 1 plots the evolution of military procurement spending relative to state output for California and Illinois, as well as military procurement 17 We deflate both regional output and military procurement spending using the national CPI for the United States. 18 A potential concern with normalizing on both sides of the regression by state-level output and population is that measurement error in these variables might bias our results. However, we use instrumental variables that are based on variation in national government spending and thus uncorrelated with this measurement error. This should eliminate any bias due to measurement error. We have also run a specification where we regress the level of output growth on the level of government spending. This yields slightly larger multipliers. 19 An alternative approach would be to use one-year changes in output and government spending and include lags and leads of government spending on the right-hand side. We have explored this and found that our biannual regression captures the bulk of the dynamics in a parsimonious way. The sum of the coefficients in the dynamic specification is somewhat larger. This is mostly due to positive coefficients on the first three leads, suggesting that there may be some anticipatory affects. However, the standard errors on each coefficient in this specification are large and dynamic panel regressions with fixed effects should be analyzed with care since they are, in general, inconsistent. Also, there may be measurement error in the timing of the procurement spending variable we use and some of the work may actually be carried out in the year after (or before) the year the procurement spending is recorded. 20 We place Delaware, Maryland, Washington DC, Virginia, and West Virginia in one region, and North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, and Florida in the other. 21 See Mintz (1992) for a discussion of political issues related to the allocation of military procurement spending.
760 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 California National Illinois 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 Figure 1. Prime Military Contract Spending as a Fraction of State GDP spending relative to total output for the United States as a whole.22 First, notice that most of the variation in national military spending is driven by geopolitical events— such as the Vietnam War, Soviet invasion of Afghanistan, and 9/11. Second, it is clear from the figure that military spending in California is systematically more sensitive to movements in national military spending than military spending in Illinois. The 1966 –1971 Vietnam War drawdown illustrates this. Over this period, military procurement in California fell by 2.5 percentage points (almost twice the national average), while military procurement in Illinois fell by only about 1 percentage point (about 2/3 the national average). We use this variation in the sensitivity of military spending across regions to national military buildups and drawdowns to identify the effects of government spending shocks. Our identifying assumption is that the United States does not embark on a military buildup because states that receive a disproportionate amount of military spending are doing poorly relative to other states. This assumption is similar—but weaker than—the common identifying assumption in the empirical literature on the effects of national military spending, that variation in national military spending is exogenous to the US business cycle. We employ two separate approaches to constructing instruments that capture the differential sensitivity of military spending across regions to national military buildups and drawdowns.23 Our baseline approach is to instrument for state or region military procurement using total national procurement interacted with a state or region dummy. The “first stage” in the two-stage least squares interpretation of this procedure is to regress changes in state spending on changes in aggregate spending and fixed effects allowing for different sensitivities across different states. This 22 Below, we will sometimes refer to spending relative to GDP simply as spending and the change in spending divided by GDP simply as the change in spending, for simplicity. 23 Murtazashvili and Wooldridge (2008) derive conditions for consistency of the fixed effects instrumental variables estimator we employ for a setting in which the multiplier varies across states.
図
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 761 Table 1—States Most Sensitive to Aggregate Military Buildups Missouri Connecticut Texas Vermont New Hampshire Massachusetts Kansas California Georgia Louisiana Note: The table lists the ten states for which log state military procurement spending increases the most when log national military procurement spending increases in descending order. yields scaled versions of changes in national spending as fitted values for each state. Table 1 lists the states for which state procurement spending is most sensitive to variation in national procurement spending. We also employ a simpler “Bartik” approach to constructing instruments (Bartik 1991). In this case, we scale national spending for each state by the average level of spending in that state relative to state output in the first five years of our sample.24 We estimate the effects of military spending on employment and inflation using an analogous approach. For employment, the regression is analogous to equation (1) except that the left-hand-side variable is ( L it − L it−2 )/ L it−2 , where L it is the employment rate (employment divided by population). For the inflation regression, the left-hand-side variable is ( Pit − Pit−2 )/ Pit−2 , where Pit is the price level. US states and regions are much more open economies than the United States as a whole. Using data from the US Commodity Flow Survey and National Income and Product Accounts, we estimate that roughly 30 percent of the consumption basket of the typical region we use in our analysis is imported from other regions (see Section IIID for details). Even though a large majority of goods are imported, the overall level of openness of US regions is modest because services account for a large fraction of output and are much more local. This estimate suggests that our regions are comparable in openness to mid-sized European countries, such as Spain. B. Subcontracting of Prime Military Contracts An important question with regard to the use of prime military contract data is to what extent the interpretation of these data might be affected by subcontracting to firms in other states. Fortunately, a second source of data exists on actual shipments to the government from defense oriented industries. These data were gathered by the Census Bureau over the period 1963 –1983 as an appendage to the Annual Survey of Manufacturers. They have rarely been used, perhaps because no electronic version previously existed. We digitized these data from microfilm. 24 Nekarda and Ramey (2011) use a similar approach to instrument for government purchases from particular industries. They use data at five year intervals to estimate the share of aggregate government spending from different industries.
762 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 35 30 25 Billion $ Billion $ 20 15 10 0 5 10 0123456789 California Prime military contracts Military shipments Massachusetts 10 Billion $ Billion $ 2002 2006 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 0123456789 30 25 20 15 10 0 5 2002 2006 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 Connecticut Texas Figure 2. Prime Military Contracts and Military Shipments Figure 2 illustrates the close relationship between these shipment data and the military procurement data for several states over this period—giving us confidence in the prime military contract data as a measure of the timing and magnitude of regional military production. To summarize this relationship, we estimate the following regression of shipments from a particular state on military procurement, (2) MS it = α i + βMPS it + ε it, where MS t is the value of shipments from the Census Bureau data and MPS it is military procurement spending. This regression yields a point estimate of β = 0.96, indicating that military procurement moves on average one-for-one with the value of shipments. The small differences between the two series probably indicate that they both measure regional production with some error. As we discuss below, one advantage of the instrumental variables approach we adopt is that it helps adjust for this type of measurement error. C. Effects of Government Spending Shocks The first row of Table 2 reports the open economy relative multiplier β in regression (1) for our baseline instruments. Standard errors are in parentheses and are clustered by states or regions.25 In the second row of Table 2, we present an analogous set of results using a broader measure of military spending that combines military procurement spending with compensation of military employees for each 25 Our standard errors thus allow for arbitrary correlation over time in the error term for a given state or region. They also allow for heteroskedasticity.
Vol. 104 No. 3state or region. We present results for output both deflated by national CPI and our measure of state CPI.26The point estimates of β for the output regression range from 1.4 to 1.9, while the point estimates of β for the employment regression range from 1.3 to 1.8. The estimates using regional data are, in general, slightly larger than those based on state data, though the differences are small and statistically insignificant. The standard errors for the state regressions range from 0.3– 0.4, while those for the region regres-sions range from 0.6– 0.9. As is clear from Figure 1, the variation we use to estimate the multiplier is dominated by a few military buildups and drawdowns.These results control for short-term movements in population associated with gov-ernment spending by running the regressions on per capita variables. The last column of Table 2 looks directly at population movements by estimating an analogous speci-fication to equation (1) where the left-hand-side variable is (Pop it − Pop it−2 )/Pop it−2and the right-hand-side government spending variable is constructed from the level of government spending and output rather than per capita government spending and output. We find that the population responses to government spending shocks are small and cannot be distinguished from zero for the two year time horizon we con-sider.27 We also present estimates of the effects of military spending on consumer prices. These are statistically insignificantly different from zero, ranging from close to zero to a small positive number.Figure 3 gives a visual representation of our main specification for output. The figure plots averages of changes in output against predicted military spending (based on our first-stage regression), grouped by 30 quantiles of the predicted military spending variable. Both variables are demeaned by year and state fixed effects. The 26 When deflating by our measure of state CPI in Table 2, we impute the state CPI’s for the first two years using our baseline instrumental variables regression of state CPI on procurement spending.27 Our estimates appear consistent with existing estimates of regional population dynamics. Blanchard and Katz (1992) show that population dynamics are important in determining the dynamics of unemployment over longer horizons.
図3
764 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 0.02 0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.005 0 0.005 0.01 Figure 3. Quantiles of Change in Output versus Predicted Change in Military Spending Notes: The figure shows averages of changes in output and predicted military spending (based on our first-stage regression), grouped by 30 quantiles of the predicted military spending variable. Both variables are demeaned by year and state fixed effects. vast majority of points in the figure are located in the northeast and southwest quadrants, leading to a positive coefficient in our IV regression. To assess the robustness of our results to outliers, we have experimented with dropping states and regions with especially large or small estimated sensitivity of spending to national spending and this slightly raises the estimated open economy relative multiplier.28 In Table 3, we report results for the simpler “Bartik” approach to constructing instruments. For output, this approach yields an open economy relative multiplier of roughly 2.5 for the states and 2.8 for the regions. For employment, this approach also yields larger open economy relative multipliers than our baseline specification—1.8 for states and 2.5 for regions. Our estimates using the Bartik-type instruments are somewhat less precise than those using our baseline instruments. This arises because, in constructing this instrument, we use the level of spending in each state as a proxy for the sensitivity of state spending to national spending—but it is an imperfect proxy. Table 3 also reports a number of alternative specifications for the effects of military procurement on output and employment designed to evaluate the robustness of our results. We report the output multiplier when per capita output is constructed using a measure of the working age population as opposed to the total population.29 We add the price of oil interacted with state dummies as controls to our baseline regression. 28 Missouri and Connecticut have substantially higher estimated sensitivity of spending to national spending than other states and North Dakota has a substantially negative estimated sensitivity (alone among the states). Dropping any combination of these states from our baseline regression slightly raises our multiplier estimate. Dropping all three yields 1.88 (0.57). 29 State-level measures of population by age group are available from the Census Bureau starting in 1970. We define the working age population as the population between the ages of 19 and 64.
表3
Vol. 104 No. 3We add the real interest rate interacted with state dummies as controls to our baseline regression. We estimate the employment regression using the BEA’s employment series (available from 1969) instead of BLS payroll employment. Table 3 shows that these specifications all yield similar results to our baseline estimates.We have extensively investigated the small-sample properties of our estimation approach using Monte Carlo simulations. These simulations indicate that neither the regional regressions nor the regressions using the Bartik-type instruments suf-fer from bias associated with weak or many instruments. However, our estimates of the state regressions using our baseline instruments are likely to be conserva-tive in the sense of underestimating the open economy relative multiplier for states by roughly 10 percent (implying that the true state-level open economy relative multiplier is 1.65 rather than 1.43). Intuitively, this downward bias arises because instrumental variables does not fully correct for endogeneity in small samples when instruments are weak or when many instruments are used—i.e., IV is biased in the direction of OLS.30 Table 3 also reports results using the LIML estimator, which is 30 See Stock, Wright, and Yogo (2002) for an overview of this issue. The concern is that the first stage of the IV procedure may pick up some of the endogenous variation in the explanatory variable in the presence of a large num-ber of instruments. In contrast to the canonical examples discussed in Stock, Wright, and Yogo (2002), this actually
766 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 not affected by the presence of many instruments. This yields an output multiplier of roughly 2.0.31 Our Monte Carlo simulation also allows us to assess the small sample properties of the standard errors we report. Our simulations imply that the asymptotic standard errors for the region regressions are slightly smaller than their small-sample counterparts: the standard 95 percent confidence interval based on the standard errors reported in Table 2 is, in fact, a 90 percent confidence interval. This adjustment arises from the well-known small-sample bias in clustered standard errors in the presence of a small number of clusters. This does not apply to the statelevel regressions for which the asymptotic standard errors almost exactly replicate the small sample results from our simulations. A potential concern with interpreting our results would arise if states receiving large amounts of military spending were more cyclically sensitive than other states. We have compared the cyclical sensitivity of states that receive large and small amounts of military spending. The standard deviation of output growth is almost identical in states with above-median military spending and in states with belowmedian military spending, indicating that a difference in overall cyclical sensitivity is not driving our results.32 Davis, Loungani, and Mahidhara (1997) finds smaller employment multipliers when using data from the Current Population Survey (CPS) than when using CES data. They argue that this may be due to shifts in employment between the selfemployed sector and more formal sectors, since self-employment is only measured in the CPS. We have run regression (1) with CPS data. In this case, the sample period is 1976 –2006 and we use the Bartik-type instruments to avoid the difficulties associated with the many instrument problem discussed above given this short sample period. The point estimates using CPS data are 1.4 (0.5). Using CES data for the same sample period yields 1.8 (0.4). The estimate based on CPS data is, thus, smaller, though not significantly so. This provides some suggestive evidence of shifts between self-employment and the more formal sector. Ramey (2011) argues that news about military spending leads actual spending by several quarters and that this has important implications for the estimation of fiscal multipliers. When we add future spending as a regressor in regression (1), the coeff icient on this variable is positive and the sum of the coefficients on the government spending rises somewhat. This suggests that our baseline specification somewhat
biases us away from finding a statistically significant result in small samples, since the OLS estimates in our case are close to zero. Our Monte Carlo analysis is roughly consistent with the asymptotic results reported in Stock and Yogo (2005). The partial R 2 of the excluded instruments, a statistic frequently used to gauge the “strength” of instruments, is 12 percent for the state regressions and 18 percent for the region regressions. However, because we use a large number of instruments in our baseline case—one for each state or region—the Cragg-Donald (1993) first stage F-statistic suggested by Stock and Yogo (2005) is roughly five for our baseline specification of the state-level regressions and eight for the region-level regressions. For the simpler Bartik-type instrument specification, it is 106 for the state-level regression and 53 for the region-level regression. Our Monte Carlo analysis indicates that, while the large number of instruments in the state-level specification leads to a slight downward-bias in the coefficient on government spending, the standard error on this coefficient is unbiased because of the high R 2 of our instruments taken as a whole. We thank Marcelo Moreira, James Stock, and Motohiro Yogo for generous advice on this issue. 31 See Stock and Yogo (2005) for a discussion of the LIML estimator’s properties in settings with many instruments. The disadvantage of LIML is that its distribution has fat tails and, thus, yields large standard errors. 32 Furthermore, suppose we regress state output growth Δ Y it on scaled national output growth s iΔ Y t, where the scaling factor s i is the average level of military spending in each state relative to state output, as well as state and time fixed effects. If states with high s i are more cyclically sensitive, this regression should yield a positive coefficient on s iΔ Y t. In fact, the coefficient is slightly negative in our data. In contrast, when s iΔ Y t is replaced with s iΔ G t , this regression yields a large positive coefficient.
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 767 underestimates the multiplier by ignoring output effects associated with anticipated future spending. Table 3 also presents OLS estimates of our baseline specification for output. The OLS estimates are substantially lower than our instrumental variables estimates. One potential explanation for this is that states’ elected officials may find it easier to argue for spending at times when their states are having trouble economically. Another potential explanation is that our instruments correct for measurement error in the data on state-level prime military contracts that does not arise at the national level. Such measurement error causes an “attenuation bias” in the OLS coefficient toward zero. We can assess the importance of measurement error in explaining the difference between our IV and OLS estimates by using the shipments data discussed in Section IIB as an instrument for the prime military contract data.33 For the 1966 –1982 sample period for which we have the shipments data, this IV procedure yields an open economy relative multiplier of 1.3 (0.5), OLS yields 0.2 (0.2), and IV with the Bartik-type instrument yields 2.0 (0.4). This suggests that measurement error explains a substantial fraction of the difference between our IV and OLS estimates. Table 4 presents the results for equation (1) estimated separately by major SIC/NAICS groupings. An important point evident from Table 4 is that increases in government sector output contribute negligibly to the overall effects we estimate. The table also shows that increases in relative procurement spending are not associated with increases in other forms of military output. Effects on measured output in the government sector are less easily interpretable than effects on output in the private sector since much of government output is measured using input costs. Transfers associated with increases in public sector wages are therefore difficult to distinguish from changes in actual output. Statistically significant output responses occur in the construction, manufacturing, retail, and services sectors. D. Government Spending at High versus Low Unemployment Rates We next investigate whether the effects of government spending on the economy are larger in periods when the unemployment rate is already high. There are a variety of reasons why this could be the case. Most often cited is the idea that in an economy with greater slack, expansionary government spending is less likely to crowd out private consumption or investment.34 A second potential source of such differences is the differential response of monetary policy—central bankers may have less incentive to “lean against the wind” to counteract the effects of government spending increases if unemployment is high. We show in Section IV, however, that this second effect does not affect the size of the open economy relative multiplier since aggregate policy is “differenced out.” 33 Since the shipments data are an independent (noisy) measure of the magnitude of spending, they will correct for measurement error. But they will not correct for endogeneity due to countercyclicality of spending. 34 This might arise, for example, if unemployment leads to a higher labor supply elasticity (Hall 2009) or because of tighter capacity constraints in booms (Gordon and Krenn 2010).
表4
768THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEWMARCH 2014To investigate these issues, we estimate the following regression:(3) Y it − Y it−2 _ Y it−2 = α i + γ t + β hG it − G it−2 _ Y it−2 + ( β l − β h ) I itG it − G it−2 _ Y it−2 + ε it,where I it is an indicator for a period of low economic slack, and the effects of gov-ernment spending in high and low slack periods are given by β h and β l respectively. We define high and low slack periods in terms of the unemployment rate at the start of the interval over which the government spending occurs. We present two sets of results; one with slack defined using the national unemployment rate and the other with slack defined using the state unemployment rate.35Table 5 presents our estimates of equation (3). For output, the point estimates support the view that the effects of government spending are larger when unem-ployment is high. Depending on the specification, the open economy relative mul-tiplier lies between 3.5 and 4.5 in the high slackness periods, substantially above 35 When we base our low slack indicator I it on the national unemployment rate, we set I it = 1 for all states in years when the national unemployment rate is below its median value over our sample. When we base I it on the state unemployment rate, we set I it = 1 for state i in years when its unemployment rate is below its median over our sample period. When we define slack using the state unemployment rate, we interact the year and state fixed effects with the dummy.
表5
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 769 Table 5 —Effects of Military Spending in High versus Low Unemployment Periods Output Employment National slack State slack National slack State slack βh βl − β h 3.54 (1.55) − 2.80 (1.49) 4.31 (1.80) − 3.37 (1.84) 1.85 (0.87) − 0.75 (0.89) 1.32 (0.81) 0.03 (0.84) Notes: A shorthand for the dependent variable is stated at the top of each column. The dependent variable is a two-year change divided by the initial value in each case. All variables are per capita. Standard errors are in parentheses. The unit of observation is US states for all regressions in the table. The two regressors are (i) the two-year change in military spending and (ii) the two-year change in military spending interacted with a dummy indicating low slackness. We employ two different measures of slackness: “National slack” refers to whether the national unemployment rate is below its median value over the sample period; “State slack” refers to whether the state unemployment rate is below its median value over the sample period. This yields the effect of spending during high unemployment periods (βh ) and the difference between the effect of spending during low and high unemployment periods (βl − β h ). The national slack regressions include state and time fixed effects. The state slack regressions include state and time fixed effects interacted with the low slackness dummy. The regression are estimated by two-stage least squares. The sample period is 1966 –2006. Output is state GDP. Employment is from the BLS payroll survey. our estimates for the time period as a whole. Given the limited number of business cycles in our sample, we are not, however, able to estimate these effects with much statistical precision. The difference in the multiplier in the high and low spending periods is only moderately statistically significant (with p-values of 0.06 and 0.07). For employment, the multiplier estimates for the high slack periods are close to those for the period as a whole and the difference in the multiplier between the high and low spending periods is relatively small and statistically insignificant.36 III. A Model of Government Spending in a Monetary Union In this section, we develop a framework to help us interpret the “open economy relative multiplier” that we estimate in Section II, and relate is to the “closed economy aggregate multiplier,” which has been the focus of most earlier work on government spending multipliers. Many of the issues that arise in interpreting the open economy relative multiplier also arise in the international economics literature. The model we develop, therefore, draws heavily on earlier work on open economy business cycle models (Obstfeld and Rogoff 1995; Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan 2002), and, in particular, the literature on monetary unions (Benigno and Benigno 2003; Galí and Monacelli 2008). Our model and some of our results are closely related to the analysis of Corsetti, Kuester, and Muller (2011), who discuss government spending in a small open economy with a fixed exchange rate. The model consists of two regions that belong to a monetary and fiscal union. We refer to the regions as “home” and “foreign.” Think of the home region as the region in which the government spending shock occurs—a US state or small group 36 Other recent papers that find evidence for larger multipliers during recessions include Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) and Shoag (2010).
770 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 of states—and the foreign region as the rest of the economy. The population of the entire economy is normalized to one. The population of the home region is denoted by n. Household preferences, market structure, and firm behavior take the same form in both regions. Below, we describe the economy of the home region. A. Households The home region has a continuum of household types indexed by x. A household’s type indicates the type of labor supplied by that household. Home households of type x seek to maximize their utility given by ∞ (4) E 0 ∑ t=0 βtu( C t, L t(x)), where β denotes the household’s subjective discount factor, C t denotes household consumption of a composite consumption good, L t(x) denotes household supply of differentiated labor input x. There are an equal (large) number of households of each type. The composite consumption good in expression (4) is an index given by η _ (5) C t = [ ϕH1 _ η CHtη−1 η 1 _ + ϕF η−1 _ η CFt η _ η−1 ] , where C Ht and C Ft denote the consumption of composites of home and foreign produced goods, respectively. The parameter η > 0 denotes the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods and ϕ H and ϕ F are preference parameters that determine the household’s relative preference for home and foreign goods. It is analytically convenient to normalize ϕ H + ϕ F = 1. If ϕ H > n, household preferences are biased toward home produced goods. The subindices, C Ht and C Ft , are given by ] θ _ θ−1 (6) C Ht = [ ∫01 c ht (z ) θ−1 _ θ dz and C Ft = θ _ [ ∫01 c ft (z ) θ−1 θ dz ] _ θ−1 , where c ht(z) and c ft(z) denote consumption of variety z of home and foreign produced goods, respectively. There is a continuum of measure one of varieties in each region. The parameter θ > 1 denotes the elasticity of substitution between different varieties. Goods markets are completely integrated across regions. Home and foreign households thus face the same prices for each of the differentiated goods produced in the economy. We denote these prices by p ht(z) for home produced goods and p ft(z) for foreign produced goods. All prices are denominated in a common currency called “dollars.”
Vol. 104 No. 3Households have access to complete financial markets. There are no impediments to trade in financial securities across regions.37 Home households of type x face a flow budget constraint given by(7) P t C t + E t[ M t, t+1 B t+1 (x)] ≤ B t(x) + (1 − τ t ) W t(x) L t(x) + ∫01Ξ ht (z) dz − T t,where P t is a price index that gives the minimum price of a unit of the consump-tion good C t , B t+1(x) is a random variable that denotes the state contingent payoff of the portfolio of financial securities held by households of type x at the begin-ning of period t + 1, M t, t+1 is the stochastic discount factor that prices these payoffs in period t, τ t denotes a labor income tax levied by the government in period t, W t(x) denotes the wage rate received by home households of type x in period t, Ξ ht(z) is the profit of home firm z in period t and T t denotes lump sum taxes.38 To rule out Ponzi schemes, household debt cannot exceed the present value of future income in any state of the world.Households face a decision in each period about how much to spend on consump-tion, how many hours of labor to supply, how much to consume of each differentiated good produced in the economy and what portfolio of assets to purchase. Optimal choice regarding the trade-off between current consumption and consumption in dif-ferent states in the future yields the following consumption Euler equation:(8) u c( C t+j, L t+j(x)) __ u c( C t, L t(x)) = M t, t+j _ βj P t+j _ P t ,as well as a standard transversality condition. Subscripts on the function u denote partial derivatives. Equation (8) holds state-by-state for all j > 0. Optimal choice regarding the intratemporal trade-off between current consumption and current labor supply yields a labor supply equation:(9)u ℓ ( C t, L t(x)) _ u c( C t, L t(x)) = (1 − τ t ) W t(x) _ P t .Households optimally choose to minimize the cost of attaining the level of con-sumption C t. This implies the following demand curves for home and foreign goods and for each of the differentiated products produced in the economy:(10) C H, t = ϕ H C t ( P Ht _ P t ) −η and C F, t = ϕ F C t ( P Ft _ P t ) −η ,(11) c ht(z) = C Ht ( p ht(z) _ P Ht ) −θ and c ft (z) = C Ft ( p ft(z) _ P Ft ) −θ ,37 Section IVD discusses a version of our model with incomplete financial markets across regions.38 The stochastic discount factor M t, t+1 is a random variable over states in period t + 1. For each such state, it equals the price of the Arrow-Debreu asset that pays off in that state divided by the conditional probability of that state. See Cochrane (2005) for a detailed discussion.
772 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 where (12) and (13) _ 1−θ P Ht = [ ∫01p ht(z ) 1−θ dz ] 1 P t = [ ϕ H PHt1−η + ϕ F PFt1−η ] 1 _ _ 1 1−θ and P Ft = [ ∫01p ft(z ) 1−θ dz ] 1−η . , As we noted above, the problem of the foreign household is analogous. We, therefore refrain from describing it in detail here. It is, however, useful to note that combining the home and foreign consumption Euler equations to eliminate the common stochastic discount factor yields (14) u c( Ct∗ , Lt∗ (x)) _ u c( C t, L t(x)) = Q t, where Q t = Pt∗/P t is the real exchange rate and Pt∗ denotes the foreign price level. This is the “Backus-Smith” condition that describes optimal risk-sharing between home and foreign households (Backus and Smith 1993). For simplicity, we assume that all households—in both regions—initially have an equal amount of financial wealth. B. The Government The economy has a federal government that conducts fiscal and monetary policy. Total government spending in the home and foreign region follow exogenous AR(1) processes. Let G Ht denote government spending per capita in the home region. Total government spending in the home region is then nG Ht. For simplicity, we assume that government demand for the differentiated products produced in each region takes the same CES form as private demand. In other words, we assume that ) −θ (15) g ht(z) = G Ht (p ht (z) _ P Ht and g ft(z) = G Ft ) −θ _ (p ft(z) P Ft . The government levies both labor income and lump-sum taxes to pay for its purchases of goods. Our assumption of perfect financial markets implies that any risk associated with variation in lump-sum taxes and transfers across the two regions is undone through risk-sharing. (See Section IVD for an alternative case.) Ricardian equivalence holds in our model. We describe the policy for labor income taxes in Section IV. The federal government operates a common monetary policy for the two regions. This policy consists of the following augmented Taylor-rule for the economy-wide nominal interest rate: rtn = ρ r rt−1 n + (1 − ρ i )( ϕ π πtag + ϕ y ytag + ϕ g gtag ),
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 773 where hatted variables denote percentage deviations from steady state. The nominal interest rate is denoted rtn. It responds to variation in the weighted average of consumer price inflation in the two regions πtag = n πt + (1 − n) πt∗, where πt is consumer price inflation in the home region and πt∗ is consumer price inflation in the foreign region. It also responds to variation in the weighted average of output in the two regions ytag = n y t + (1 − n) yt∗ . Finally, it may respond directly to the weighted average of the government spending shock in the two regions gtag = n g t + (1 − n) gt∗ . C. Firms There is a continuum of firms indexed by z in the home region. Firm z specializes in the production of differentiated good z, the output of which we denote y ht (z). In our baseline model, labor is the only variable factor of production used by firms. Each firm is endowed with a fixed, nondepreciating stock of capital.39 The production function of firm z is (17) y ht (z) = f ( L t(z)). The function f is increasing and concave. It is concave because there are diminishing marginal returns to labor given the fixed amount of other inputs employed at the f irm. Labor is immobile across regions. Our model yields very similar results to a model in which labor and capital are assumed to be equally mobile and the government spending shock is to per capita spending.40 We follow Woodford (2003) in assuming that each firm belongs to an industry x and that there are many firms in each industry. The goods in industry x are produced using labor of type x and all f irms in industry x change prices at the same time. Firm z acts to maximize its value, ∞ (18) E t ∑ j=0 M t, t+j[ p ht+j(z) y ht+j(z) − W t+j(x) L t+j(z)]. Firm z must satisfy demand for its product. The demand for firm z’s product comes from three sources: home consumers, foreign consumers, and the government. It is given by (19) y ht(z) = (nC Ht + (1 − n) CHt∗ + nG Ht ) 39 Section IVE discusses two extensions of our baseline model with investment. ) −θ ( p ht(z) _ P Ht . 40 If labor and capital are equally mobile, factor movements simply affect the relative size of the regions. For example, a positive shock to the home region causes inward migration of both labor and capital and this makes the home region larger. But in per capita terms, the model is identical to a model without factor mobility (save a slight change in home bias) as long as the government spending shock is defined in per capita terms and the open economy relative multiplier is thus virtually identical. In contrast, if labor is more mobile then capital, inward migration in response to a positive government spending shock will lower the capital-labor ratio in the home region and, through this channel, lower the per capita government spending multiplier (and vice versa if capital is more mobile than labor).
774 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 Firm z is therefore subject to the following constraint: ) −θ (20) (nC Ht + (1 − n) CHt∗ + nG Ht ) ( p ht(z) _ P Ht ≤ f ( L t (z)). Firm z takes its industry wage W t(x) as given. Optimal choice of labor demand by the firm is given by (21) W t (x) = f ℓ ( L t(z)) S t(z), where S t(z) denotes the firm’s nominal marginal cost (the Lagrange multiplier on equation (20) in the firm’s constrained optimization problem). Firm z can reoptimize its price with probability 1 − α as in Calvo (1983). With probability α it must keep its price unchanged. Optimal price setting by firm z in periods when it can change its price implies (22) p ht (z) = θ _ ∞ α j M t, t+j y ht+j(z) θ − 1 E t ∑ j=0 __ ∞ E t ∑ k=0 α kM t, t+k y ht+j(z) S t+j(z). Intuitively, the firm sets its price equal to a constant markup over a weighted average of current and expected future marginal cost. D. Calibration of Preferences and Technology We consider the following two forms for the utility function: (23) (24) u ( C t, L t(x)) = Ct1−σ−1 _ 1 − σ −1 − χ L t (x ) 1+ν−1 _ 1 + ν −1 , u ( C t , L t(x)) = ( C t − χ L t(x ) 1+ν−1 /(1 + ν −1 ) ) 1−σ−1 ___ 1 − σ −1 . In the first utility specification, consumption and labor enter separably. They are therefore neither complements nor substitutes. The second utility function is adopted from Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Huffman (1988). We refer to this utility function as representing GHH preferences. Consumption and labor are complements for households with GHH preferences. Recently, Monacelli and Perotti (2008), Bilbiie (2011), and Hall (2009) have emphasized the implications of consumption-labor complementarities for the government spending multiplier. For both specifications of utility, we must specify values for σ and ν (χ is irrelevant when utility is separable and determined by other parameters in the GHH case). In both cases, ν is the Frisch-elasticity of labor supply. We set ν = 1. This value is somewhat higher than values estimated in microeconomic studies of employed workers, but relatively standard in macroeconomics. The higher value is meant to capture variation in labor on the extensive margin—such as variation in unemployment and retirement (Hall 2009, Chetty et al. 2011). As Hall (2009) emphasizes,
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 775 assuming a high labor supply elasticity raises the government spending multiplier. For the separable utility specification, σ denotes the intertemporal elasticity of substitution (IES). There is little agreement within the macroeconomics literature on the appropriate values for the IES. Hall (1988) estimates the IES to be close to zero, while Bansal and Yaron (2004), Gruber (2006), and Nakamura et al. (2013) argue for values above 1. We set σ = 1, which yields balanced growth for the model with separable preferences, σ = 1. We set the subjective discount factor equal to β = 0.99, the elasticity of substitution across varieties equal to θ = 7 and the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods to η = 2.41 Larger values of η yield more expenditure switching between regions in response to regional shocks and thus lower open economy relative multipliers. We assume the production function f ( L t(z)) = L t(z ) a and set a = 2 _ 3 . Regarding the frequency with which firms can change their prices, we consider two cases: α = 0 (i.e., fully flexible prices) and α = 0.75 (which implies that firms reoptimize their prices on average once a year). Rigid prices imply that relative prices across regions respond sluggishly to regional shocks. We set the size of the home region to n = 0.1. This roughly corresponds to the size of the average region in our regional regressions (where we divide the United States into ten regions). The value of the open economy relative multiplier in our model is relatively insensitive to the size of n. We set the steady state value of government purchases as a fraction of output to 0.2. We log-linearize the equilibrium conditions of the model and use the methods of Sims (2001) to find the unique bounded equilibrium. By doing this we rule out the types of nonlinearities we find suggestive evidence for in Section IID. We use data from the US Commodity Flow Survey (CFS) and the US National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) to set the home-bias parameter ϕ H. The CFS reports data on shipments of goods within and between states in the United States. It covers shipments between establishments in the mining, manufacturing, wholesale, and retail sectors. For the average state in 2002, 38 percent of shipments were within state and 50 percent of shipments were within region. However, roughly 40 percent of all shipments in the CFS are from wholesalers to retailers, and the results of Hillberry and Hummels (2003) suggest that a large majority of these are likely to be within region. Since the relevant shipments for our model are those from manufacturers to wholesalers, we assume that 83 percent of these are from another region (50 of the remaining 60 percent of shipments). To calculate the degree of home bias, we must account for the fact that a substantial fraction of output is services, which are not measured in the CFS. NIPA data indicate that goods represent roughly 30 percent of US GDP. If all inter-region trade were in goods—i.e., all services were local—imports from other regions would amount to 25 percent of total consumption (30 × 0.83 = 25). However, for the United States as a whole, services represent roughly 20 percent of international trade. Assuming that services represent the same fraction of cross-border trade for regions, total inter-region trade is 31 percent of region GDP (25/0.8 = 31). We therefore set ϕ H = 0.69. This makes our regions slightly more open than Spain and slightly less open than Portugal. We set ϕ H∗ so that overall demand for home
41 This is the same value for η as is used by Obstfeld and Rogoff (2005), and only slightly higher than the values used by Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland (1994) and Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002).
776 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 products as a fraction of overall demand for all products is equal to the size of the home population relative to the total population of the economy. This implies that ϕ H∗ = (n/(1 − n)) ϕ F. We have so far calibrated the “fundamentals”—i.e., preferences and technology— for our model economy. We leave the detailed description of government policy to the next section. We wish to draw a clear distinction between fundamentals and government policy. The former determine constraints on the potential effects of government policy. In contrast, monetary and fiscal policy are under the government’s control and therefore “choice variables” from the perspective of an optimizing government, making it relevant to consider not only the policies that have persisted in the past but also the potential effects of alternative government policies. IV. Theoretical Results In this section, we analyze the effects of government spending shocks in the model presented in Section III. We consider several different specifications for the economy’s “fundamentals” (separable versus GHH preferences, flexible versus sticky prices) as well as different specifications for aggregate monetary and tax policy. In the Neoclassical (flexible price) versions of the model, money is neutral, implying that the specification of monetary policy is irrelevant. Tax policy is, however, important and we consider two specifications for tax policy described below. In the New Keynesian (sticky price) versions of the model, monetary policy is important and we consider three specifications of monetary policy within the class of interest rate rules described by equation (16). The monetary policies we consider are: (i) a “Volcker-Greenspan” policy, (ii) a “fixed real-rate” policy, and (iii) a “fixed nominal-rate” policy. These policies are designed to imply successively less “leaning against the wind” by the central bank in response to inflationary government spending shocks. The “Volcker-Greenspan” policy is meant to mimic the policy of the US Federal Reserve during the VolckerGreenspan period. For this case, we set the parameters in equation (16) to ρ =0.8, ϕ π = 1.5, ϕ y = 0.5, and ϕ g = 0.42 This specification of monetary policy implies that the monetary authority aggressively raises the real interest rate to curtail the inflationary effects of a government spending shock. Under the “fixed real-rate” policy, the central bank maintains a fixed real interest rate in response to government spending shocks. However, to guarantee price-level determinacy, the central bank responds aggressively to the inflationary effects of all other shocks. Under the “fixed nominal-rate policy,” the central bank maintains a fixed nominal interest rate in response to government spending shocks. But as with the fixed real-rate policy, it responds aggressively to the inflationary effects of all other shocks. We describe the details of how the fixed real-rate and fixed nominal-rate policies are implemented in online Appendix A. The fixed nominalrate policy is a close cousin of the zero lower bound scenario analyzed in detail in Eggertsson (2010); Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011); and Mertens and Ravn (2010). It is, in a sense, the opposite of the aggressive “leaning against 42 Many recent papers have estimated monetary rules similar to the one we adopt for the Volcker-Greenspan period (see, e.g., Taylor 1993 and 1999; Clarida, Galí, and Gertler 2000).
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 777 the wind” embodied in the Volcker-Greenspan policy because an inflationary shock generates a fall in real interest rates (since nominal rates are held constant). The f ixed real-rate policy charts a middle ground. We consider two specifications for tax policy. Our baseline tax policy is one in which government spending shocks are financed completely by lump-sum taxes. Under this policy, all distortionary taxes remain fixed in response to the government spending shock. The second tax policy we consider is a “balanced budget” tax policy. Under this policy, labor income taxes vary in response to government spending shocks such that the government’s budget remains balanced throughout: (25) nP Ht G Ht + (1 − n) P Ft G Ft = τ t ∫ W t (x) L t(x) dx. This policy implies that an increase in government spending is associated with an increase in distortionary taxes. We assume that the government spending shocks follow an AR(1) process and estimate the persistence of this process using data on aggregate military procurement spending. This yields a quarterly AR(1) coefficient of 0.933.43 We also in some cases consider the implications of more transitory government spending shocks. We present results for both the closed economy aggregate multiplier that has been studied in much of the previous literature and the open economy relative multiplier that we provide estimates for in Section II and has been the focus of much recent work using subregional data (Acconcia, Corsetti, and Simonelli 2011; ChodorowReich et al. 2012; Clemens and Miran 2012; Cohen, Coval, and Malloy 2011; Fishback and Kachanovskaya 2010; Serrato and Wingender 2010; Shoag 2010; Wilson 2012). We begin in Sections IVA and IVB by describing results for the case of additively separable preferences. We then consider the case of GHH preferences in Section IVC. Finally, in Section IVE, we consider an extension of our model that incorporates investment. A. The Closed Economy Aggregate Multiplier We define the closed economy aggregate multiplier analogously to the previous literature on multipliers (e.g., Barro and Redlick 2011) as the response of total output (combining home and foreign production) to total government spending, i.e., β in the regression, agg (26) Ytagg − Yt−2 _ Yt−2 agg agg = α + β Gtagg − Gt−2 _ Yt−2 agg + ε t, where Ytagg denotes aggregate output and Gtagg denotes aggregate government spending. This regression is identical to the one we use to measure the open economy relative multiplier—equation (1)—except that we are using aggregate variables and have dropped the time fixed effects. We calculate this object by simulating quarterly
43 Our aggregate military procurement spending data is annual. We use a simulated method of moments approach to estimate the persistence of our quarterly AR(1) process. We describe this procedure in detail in online Appendix B.
778 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 Table 6—Government Spending Multiplier in Separable Preferences Model Closed economy aggregate multiplier Open economy relative multiplier Panel A. Sticky prices Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy Constant real rate Constant nominal rate Constant nominal rate (ρg = 0.85) Panel B. Flexible prices Constant income tax rates Balanced budget 0.20 1.00 ∞ 1.70 0.39 0.32 0.83 0.83 0.83 0.90 0.43 0.43 Notes: The table reports the government spending multiplier for output deflated by the regional CPI for the model presented in the text with the separable preferences specification. Panel A presents results for the model with sticky prices, while panel B presents results for the model with flexible prices. The first three rows differ only in the monetary policy being assumed. The fourth row varies the persistence of the government spending shock relative to the baseline parameter values. The fifth and sixth rows differ only in the tax policy being assumed. data from the model described in Section III, time-aggregating it up to an annual frequency, and running the regression (26) on this data. The first column of Table 6 reports results on the closed economy aggregate multiplier. These results clearly indicate that the closed economy aggregate multiplier is highly sensitive to aggregate monetary and tax policy—a point emphasized by Woodford (2011); Eggertsson (2010); Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011); and Baxter and King (1993). In the New Keynesian model with a Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy, it is quite low—only 0.20. The low multiplier arises because the monetary authority reacts to the inflationary effects of the increase in government spending by raising real interest rates. This counteracts the expansionary effects of the spending shock. For monetary policies that respond less aggressively to inflationary shocks, the closed economy multiplier can be substantially larger. For the constant real-rate policy, the multiplier is one (Woodford 2011). Intuitively, since the real interest rate remains constant rather than rising when spending increases there is no “crowding out” of consumption, implying that output rises one-for-one with government spending. For the constant nominal-rate policy, the multiplier is larger than one and can become very large depending on parameters. It is 1.70 if the government spending shock is relatively transient (half-life of one year, ρ g = 0.85 ). With more persistent government spending shocks ( ρ g = 0.933 ) it becomes infinite. However, it should be kept in mind that the case we are considering is effectively assuming that the economy stays at the zero lower bound indefinitely. If the economy is expected to revert to, e.g., a Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy before some fixed future point the multiplier is finite.44 The intuition for the large multipliers with a constant nominal-rate policy is that the government spending shock raises inflationary expectations, which lowers the real interest rate and thereby “crowds in” private demand. 44 Similar issues regarding the finiteness of the zero lower bound multiplier arise in Eggertsson (2010) and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011).
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 779 The second panel of Table 6 presents results for the Neoclassical model. These results clearly indicate that the closed economy aggregate multiplier also depends on the extent to which the government spending is financed by contemporaneous distortionary taxes. If the spending is financed by an increase in distortionary taxes in such a way as to maintain a balanced budget period-by-period (as opposed to by lump-sum taxes), the multiplier falls by about a fourth to 0.32. If distortionary taxes are reduced in concert with an increase in government spending the aggregate multiplier can be substantially higher (though we do not report this in the table). It is useful to pause for a moment to consider why price rigidity—the feature that distinguishes the New Keynesian and Neoclassical models we consider—matters so much in determining effects of government spending. For concreteness, consider a transitory shock to government spending at the zero lower bound. This shock puts pressure on prices to rise. In the Neoclassical model with a constant money supply, prices immediately jump up and begin falling. This implies that the real interest rate rises on impact (because prices are falling) and crowds out private spending. In the New Keynesian model, however, prices rise only gradually since many are rigid in the short run. This implies that the real interest rate falls on impact and thus boosts private spending. It is this difference in the response of the real interest rate to government spending shocks—caused by a difference in the flexibility of prices—that explains the difference in the multiplier across these models. The sensitivity of the closed economy aggregate multiplier to aggregate monetary and tax policy probably explains some of the wide range of estimates in the empirical literature. Most economists agree that the extent to which the Federal Reserve has “leaned against the wind” has varied substantially over the last century (see, e.g., Clarida, Galí, and Gertler 2000). This sensitivity carries over to other variables. Much recent work on the effects of fiscal policy has focused on consumption, real wages, and markups (Ramey 2011, Perotti 2008). In our New Keynesian model with Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy, the closed economy aggregate multiplier is negative for all three of these variables, while it is positive for more accommodative monetary policy. The enormous variation in possible values for the closed economy aggregate multiplier depending on the policy environment underscores the difficulty of using the closed economy aggregate multiplier to distinguish among alternative views of how government spending affects the economy. Under “normal” monetary policy (i.e., the Volcker-Greenspan policy), it may be exceedingly difficult to distinguish between the Neoclassical and New Keynesian models. Both frameworks predict little effect of government spending on output. Yet this does not imply that the models have similar implications overall. While the Neoclassical model continues to generate a low aggregate multiplier in the fixed nominal rate scenario that we use to proxy for the zero lower bound, the New Keynesian model can generate extremely large multipliers in this environment. In the next section, we illustrate that the open economy relative multiplier has important advantages when it comes to distinguishing between different views of how government spending affects the economy, because it is not sensitive to the specification of aggregate monetary and tax policy but rather to the relative policies across regions—which are precisely pinned down in a monetary and fiscal union.
780 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 B. The Open Economy Relative Multiplier Contrast the wide range of different closed economy aggregate multipliers produced by our model for different monetary policies with the complete stability of the open economy relative multiplier reported in the second column of Table 6. The open economy relative multiplier is calculated by estimating equation (1) using the regional data from the model—the same specification we use in our empirical analysis.45 For all three specifications of monetary policy we consider, the open economy relative multiplier is 0.83. Furthermore, the fifth and sixth rows of Table 6 present results for the different specifications of tax policy in the Neoclassical model and illustrate that the open economy relative multiplier is also completely insensitive to aggregate tax policy. The open economy relative multiplier is sensitive to economic fundamentals (e.g., the degree of price rigidity) and to region-specific policies (e.g., the persistence of the regional government spending shock) as we discuss below. Intuitively, the open economy relative multiplier is independent of aggregate policy because we “difference out” aggregate shocks and aggregate policy by including time fixed effects in the regression. In a monetary union, the monetary authority cannot respond to a shock in one region by making monetary policy tighter in that region alone. The relative monetary policy between the two regions is, therefore, held fixed by the monetary union in a very precise way, regardless of the stance of aggregate monetary policy. In this sense, the open economy relative multiplier is akin to the closed economy aggregate multiplier for a relatively accommodative aggregate monetary policy—more accommodative than US monetary policy under Volcker and Greenspan. The open economy relative multiplier is smaller than one for a wide range of parameters in our model. This is most easily seen by considering the “Backus-Smith” risk-sharing condition c t − ct∗ = σ q t. An increase in home government spending will increase the relative price of home goods and therefore decrease the “real exchange rate” ( Q t = Pt∗ / P t ). By the Backus-Smith condition, this implies that home consumption must fall relative to foreign consumption. In other words, government spending “crowds out” private spending in relative terms implying a relative multiplier that is smaller than one. Since the relative nominal interest rate is constant in response to a regional government spending shock, it is tempting to think that this situation is analogous to the zero lower bound, where the nominal interest rate is fixed at zero in response to government spending shocks. As in the zero lower bound case, an increase in relative government spending in the home region can raise expected inflation, lowering relative short-term real interest rates. However, unlike the zero lower bound case, the relative long-term real interest rate does not fall in response to a fiscal shock. The fiscal shock leads to an immediate rise in relative prices and expectations of further increases in the short term. This lowers the relative short term real interest rate. However, since a transitory shock to spending does not lead to a permanent change in relative prices and the exchange rate is fixed within the monetary union, any short term increase in prices in one region relative to the other region must be
45 Specifically, we take a linear approximation of the dependent and independent variables in equation (1) and run the regression using these approximate variables. See online Appendix C for details.
図4
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 781 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 Price level Real interest rate 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75
80 Figure 4. Prices and Real Interest Rates after a Government Spending Shock Note: The figure plots the relative price level and the relative real interest rate in the two regions for the model with separable preferences after a positive government spending shock to the home region. undone by a fall in relative prices in that region later on.46 In fact, after their initial jump, relative prices are anticipated to fall more in the long run than they are anticipated to rise further in the short run. This implies that the relative long-term real interest rate actually rises slightly in the home region in response to an increase in government spending.47 To more clearly see the intuition for this result, Figure 4 presents the impulse response of the price level and the real interest rate in the home region relative to the foreign region after a government spending shock in our model. The home price level rises for several periods, but then falls back to its original level. This movement in prices implies that the real interest rate in the home region initially falls, but then rises above its steady state level for a prolonged period. Figure 5 shows what happens to consumption in the home region relative to the foreign region after a government spending shock. Despite the short-run fall in the real interest rate, consumption falls. This is because households anticipate high real rates in the future— equivalently, they face a high current long-term real interest rate—and therefore cut their consumption. Since the relevant interest rate for consumption decisions—the long-term real interest rate—actually rises slightly in response to an increase in government spending irrespective of the persistence of the shock and other parameters, the fixed relative nominal interest rate policy in a monetary union is fundamentally different from
46 Parsley and Wei (1996) present evidence for rapid convergence of relative prices following regional shocks using data for US regions. 47 Corsetti, Kuester, and Muller (2011) show that the same logic holds for the case of a small open economy with a fixed exchange rate.
図5
782 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 Consumption Real interest rate 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 Figure 5. Consumption and Real Interest Rate after a Government Spending Shock Note: The figure plots the relative consumption and the relative real interest rate in the two regions for the model with separable preferences after a positive government spending shock to the home region. a zero lower bound setting in a closed economy in which the long-term real interest rate falls in response to a government spending shock. The response of relative longterm real interest rates in our setting is closest to the fixed real interest rate case in the closed economy setting. Table 6 shows that the open economy relative multiplier is, in fact, 0.83 for our baseline parameter values. This is far below the zero lower bound multipliers emphasized by Eggertsson (2010) and Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011), but just slightly lower than the closed economy aggregate multiplier for a fixed real rate monetary policy. C. Model with GHH Preferences The models we have considered so far have generated predictions for the open economy relative multiplier substantially below the point estimate of roughly 1.5 that we obtained in Section II. We next consider a model with GHH preferences that is capable of fitting this feature of our empirical estimates.48 GHH preferences imply that consumption and labor are complements. This complementarity is intended to represent the extra consumption on food away from home, clothing, gas, and the like that often arises in the context of work (Aguiar and Hurst 2005 and Aguiar, Hurst, and Karabarbounis 2013 present empirical evidence for such complementarities).49
48 Models with hand-to-mouth consumers of the type studied by Galí, López-Salido, and Valles (2007) may also have the potential to generate large open economy relative multipliers. 49 Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2012) estimate a rich business cycle model with Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) preferences—-which nests GHH and King, Plosser, and Rebelo (1988) preferences as special cases. The values
表7
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 783 Table 7–Government Spending Multiplier in GHH Model Closed economy aggregate multiplier Open economy relative multiplier Panel A. Sticky prices Volcker-Greenspan monetary policy Constant real rate Constant nominal rate Constant nominal rate (ρg = 0.50) Panel B. Flexible prices Constant income tax rates Balanced budget 0.12 7.00 ∞ 8.73 0.00 − 0.18 1.42 1.42 1.42 2.04 0.30 0.30 Notes: The table reports the government spending multiplier for output deflated by the regional CPI for the model presented in the text with the GHH preferences specification. Panel A presents results for the model with sticky prices, while panel B presents results for the model with f lexible prices. The first three rows differ only in the monetary policy being assumed. The fourth row varies the persistence of the government spending shock relative to the baseline parameter values. The fifth and sixth rows differ only in the tax policy being assumed. Previous work by Monacelli and Perotti (2008), Bilbiie (2011), and Hall (2009) has shown that allowing for complementarities between consumption and labor can have powerful implications for the government spending multiplier. The basic intuition is that, in response to a government spending shock, households must work more to produce the additional output. This raises consumption demand since consumption is complementary to labor. But to be able to consume more, still more production must take place, further raising the effects on output. The second column of Table 7 presents estimates of the open economy relative multiplier for the model with GHH preferences. The New Keynesian model with GHH preferences can match our empirical findings in Section II of an open economy multiplier of roughly 1.5 (assuming a quarterly persistence of ρ g = 0.933 as in the military spending data). As in the model with separable preferences, this statistic is entirely insensitive to the specification of aggregate policies. For the case of more transitory government spending shocks ( ρ g = 0.5), the open economy relative multiplier rises to 2.0. The Neoclassical model, however, continues to generate a low multiplier (0.3) in this model. Figure 6 plots relative output and consumption in the New Keynesian model with GHH preferences after a positive shock to home government spending. Both output and consumption rise on impact by a little more than twice the amount of the shock. They then both fall more rapidly than the shock. The fact that the initial rise in consumption is as large as the rise in output—which is partly fulfilling increased orders from the government—implies that the home region responds to the shock by running a trade deficit in the short run. Consumption eventually falls below its steady state level for a period of time. During this time, the home region is running a trade surplus. Intuitively, the complementarity between consumption and labor implies that home households want to shift their consumption toward periods of high work effort associated with positive government spending shocks.
that they estimate for the preference parameters of their model are those for which Jaimovich-Rebelo preferences reduce to GHH preferences.
図6
784 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 0.00 0.50 Output Consumption Government spending 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Figure 6. Output and Consumption after a Government Spending Shock in GHH Model Note: The figure plots the relative output and consumption in the two regions for the model with GHH preferences after a positive government spending shock to the home region. How does the introduction of GHH preference affect the closed economy aggregate multiplier? The first column of Table 7 reports the closed economy aggregate multiplier in our model with GHH preferences. Under certain circumstances—in particular, the case of a fixed nominal rate rule meant to proxy for the zero lower bound—this model can generate an extremely large closed economy aggregate multiplier. However, if monetary policy is highly responsive to output as in the case of Volcker-Greenspan policy, the New Keynesian model with GHH preferences implies a low closed economy aggregate multiplier, just as the Neoclassical model does. Table 7 makes clear that the introduction of GHH preferences does not generically increase the closed economy aggregate multiplier. In the Neoclassical model, introducing GHH preferences lowers the closed economy aggregate multiplier (to zero) by eliminating the wealth effect on labor supply.50 The introduction of GHH preferences also lowers the closed economy aggregate multiplier in the New Keynesian model when monetary policy responds aggressively to the inflationary effects of government spending shocks—as in the case of the Volcker-Greenspan policy rule. For this policy, the endogenous increase in real interest rates chokes off the chain of increases in output, employment, and consumption that otherwise generates a large multiplier in the GHH model. A key reason why the introduction of GHH
50 In the New Keynesian model, government spending shocks affect the markup of prices over marginal costs and, therefore, affect output by shifting labor demand. Similarly, the open economy relative multiplier in the Neoclassical model with GHH preferences is nonzero because the government spending shock shifts the labor supply curve as a function of the real product wage.
表8
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 785 Table 8 —Government Spending Multipliers in Incomplete Markets Model Closed economy aggregate multiplier Open economy relative multiplier Panel A. Sticky prices Baseline model (complete markets) Incomplete markets, locally financed Incomplete markets, federally financed Panel B. Flexible prices Baseline model (complete markets) Incomplete markets, locally financed Incomplete markets, federally financed 0.20 0.18 0.18 0.39 0.39 0.39 0.83 0.84 0.90 0.43 0.41 0.40 Notes: The table reports the government spending multiplier for output deflated by the regional CPI for a version of the model presented in the text with separable utility in which the only f inancial asset traded across regions is a noncontingent bond. Panel A presents results for the model with sticky prices, while panel B presents results for the model with flexible prices. preferences raises the open economy relative multiplier when compared to the case of separable preferences is thus that the monetary union implies an accommodative “relative” monetary policy—sufficiently accommodative not to choke off the increase in relative output. Summing up our results thus far, our estimates of equation (1), based on the military procurement data, yield an open economy relative multiplier of roughly 1.5. This lies far above the open economy relative multipliers for the Neoclassical model—which are below 0.5 for both separable preferences and GHH preferences. Our empirical estimate of 1.5 is also substantially higher than the open economy relative multiplier of 0.83 implied by the New Keynesian model with separable preferences. The New Keynesian model with GHH preferences, however, is able to match the open economy relative multiplier we estimate in the data. Our results are thus consistent with a model in which demand shocks can have large effects on output— if monetary policy is sufficiently accommodative (as it is at the zero lower bound). D. Model with Incomplete Financial Markets The model we develop in Section III features complete financial markets across regions of the economy. This implies that all risk associated with differential taxes and labor income across regions—possibly arising from government spending shocks—is perfectly shared. In a recent paper, Farhi and Werning (2012) have shown that in a monetary union with incomplete financial markets across regions, regional government spending multipliers can differ substantially depending on whether the spending is financed by local taxes or federal taxes. Table 8 presents open economy relative multipliers for a version of our model in which the only financial asset that is traded across regions is a noncontingent bond. For this model, we present results for two assumptions about how spending is financed: locally financed spending and federally financed spending. Table 8 shows that these two versions of the incomplete markets model yield similar results about the open economy relative multiplier to the baseline complete markets model. In the case of federally financed spending, the open economy relative multiplier rises to 0.90 when prices are sticky. The intuition for this is that
786 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 home agents are wealthier as a result of the government spending (they receive labor income far in excess of the extra taxes they must pay). Since their preferences are home-biased, their increased wealth increases home demand. In the long run, the increased wealth reduces labor supply. But the first of these effects outweighs the latter, implying that the multiplier increases. What is perhaps more surprising is that even in the case of locally financed spending, the incomplete markets model yields a slightly larger open economy relative multiplier than the complete markets model when prices are sticky. In this case, home agents are not wealthier due to the government spending shock. However, they are wealthier than they would have been had they shared all risk. The reason is that the government spending shock leads to an increase in the relative price of home goods. Since home households have a stronger preference for home goods than foreign households, it is efficient for them to purchase state contingent assets that pay out when home goods are cheap and require them to pay when home goods are expensive. A home government spending shock therefore leads to a negative transfer for home agents under complete markets. When prices are flexible, the open economy relative multiplier is slightly lower in the incomplete markets model than it is with complete markets. With flexible prices, the increase in wealth associated with the government spending reduces labor supply, whereas it does not lead to a Keynesian increase in aggregate demand. This reduction in labor supply decreases the open economy relative multiplier. The effects of changes in wealth on the open economy relative multiplier are sensitive to the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods. Our baseline value for this parameter is 2. If we instead assume that this elasticity is 1, the open economy relative multiplier rises to 1.05 for federally financed spending. To be able to generate an open economy relative multiplier of 1.5, we must assume that this elasticity is below 0.6. This is a substantially lower value than most empirical studies suggest.
E. Models with Variable Capital
The model we develop in Section III abstracts from investment and capital accumulation. In Appendixes F and G we incorporate investment and capital accumulation into our model in two different ways. The specification presented in online Appendix G follows closely the setup in Woodford (2003, 2005). In this model, capital is firm-specific in that each firm owns its capital stock and faces convex investment adjustment costs at the firm level. Our baseline model is a limiting case of this model when the capital share goes to zero. This setup has been used, e.g., by Eichenbaum and Fisher (2007) and Altig et al. (2011). The specification presented in online Appendix F largely mirrors Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005). In this case, households own the capital stock and firms rent capital on a period-byperiod basis in a frictionless regional capital market. This specification also allows for variable capital utilization and investment adjustment costs at the regional level. Table 9 presents open economy relative multipliers for these models in the case when households have GHH preferences. The output multiplier for the firm-specific capital model is slightly larger than for our baseline model. Since the government spending shock is persistent, firms expect a high marginal return on capital for some
表9
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 787 Table 9—Open Economy Relative Multiplier in Models with Variable Capital Output CPI inflation Baseline model (fixed capital) Firm-specific capital model Regional capital market model Firm-specific capital model, flexible prices 1.42 1.47 0.98 0.25 0.17 0.15 0.09 0.36 Notes: The table reports the open economy relative government spending multiplier for output and CPI inflation for our baseline model with GHH preferences and the two models with variable capital, also with GHH preferences. Output is deflated by the regional CPI. time and increase investment when the shock occurs. In contrast, the model with regional capital markets yields a smaller multiplier than the baseline model. This occurs despite investment rising as in the firm-specific capital model. The main reason for the fall in the multiplier is that the regional nature of the capital market reduces the degree of strategic complementarity of the price setting decisions across firms relative to the baseline model (since firms that raise their price can costlessly reduce the amount of capital they rent). Clearly, the assumption that firms rent the capital that they use each period on frictionless regional capital markets is unrealistic. Eichenbaum and Fisher (2007) and Altig et al. (2011) show that adopting the more realistic setting of firm-specific capital helps New Keynesian models with capital match the sluggish response of prices to aggregate disturbances without resorting to unrealistic assumptions about the frequency of price adjustment or the indexing of prices. The final row of Table 9 shows that, with flexible prices, the open economy relative multiplier is close to zero in the firm-specific capital model. Table 9 also presents open economy relative multipliers for CPI inflation. The New Keynesian models generate small increases in relative inflation. This lines up well with our empirical findings on relative inflation. In contrast, the model with flexible prices counterfactually implies a much sharper rise in relative inflation rates. F. Welfare The welfare consequences of government spending depend not only on the multiplier, but also on the utility agents derive from the goods and services purchased by the government. Woodford (2011) and Werning (2012) provide an extensive discussion of the welfare consequences of government spending. To illustrate the main forces, suppose household utility can be represented by U ( C t, L t, G t ) and the production function is Y t = f ( L t ).51 Household utility may then be written as U ( Y t − G t, f−1( Y t ), G t ). Following Woodford (2011), we can differentiate this and get (27) dU _ dG = ( U C − − U L _ f L _ )dY dG + ( U G − U C ). 51 For simplicity, we abstract from investment, heterogeneous labor markets, and price dispersion due to price rigidity. And we assume that government spending is financed by lump-sum taxes.
788 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 The first term is the difference between the marginal utility of consumption and the marginal disutility of producing goods ( U L is negative), multiplied by the government spending multiplier. In a frictionless economy, this term is zero since output is chosen optimally to equate the two terms in the bracket. The second term is the difference between the marginal value of government spending and the marginal value of private spending. In a frictionless economy, thus, the government should spend up to a point where the value of an extra dollar of government spending is equal to that of private spending. In an economy with frictions, output might, however, be below its optimal level making the first term positive. In this case, it may be desirable, other things equal, to increase spending beyond the point at which the second term is equal to zero. The extent of extra desirable spending will depend on the size of the multiplier, with a larger multiplier implying that more spending is desirable. Woodford (2011) argues that monetary policy should be the tool of choice to eliminate such “output gaps” since there is no cost to using monetary policy, and this allows fiscal policy to focus on equalizing the marginal value of an extra dollar of government spending and private spending. If fiscal policy is used to eliminate output gaps, this may interfere with that second objective. Only when monetary policy is constrained—such as when the nominal interest rate is at its zero lower bound—should fiscal policy be used to eliminate output gaps. In an economy with price rigidity, welfare is also affected by the extent of inefficient price dispersion due to inflation and government spending can raise welfare to the extent it can help stabilize inflation. Werning (2012) decomposes optimal stimulus spending into an “opportunistic” part, which reflects the desire of the government to take advantage of low prices during recessions, and a true “stimulus” part, which reflects additional spending beyond this benchmark. He argues that an important part of optimal stimulus at the zero lower bound is “opportunistic” and that “stimulus” spending may optimally be zero or close to zero.
V. Conclusion
We exploit regional variation in military spending in the United States to estimate the effect of government spending on output in a monetary union. We use the fact that when the United States embarks upon a military buildup, there is a systematic tendency for spending to increase more in some states than others. For example, when aggregate military spending in the United States rises by 1 percent of GDP, military spending in California on average rises by about 3 percent of California GDP, while military spending in Illinois rises by only about 0.5 percent of Illinois GDP. Under the assumption that the United States doesn’t embark upon military buildups like the Vietnam War because states like California are doing badly relative to states like Illinois, we can use regional variation associated with these buildups to estimate the effect of a relative increase in spending on relative output. We find that when relative spending in a state increases by 1 percent of GDP, relative state GDP rises by 1.5 percent. At first glance, this multiplier estimate may seem quite large. However, it pertains to a different object than the conventional “closed economy aggregate multiplier,” in that it measures the effect of a relative change in government spending
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 789 in two different states on the relative change in output. We coin the term the “open economy relative multiplier” for this object and develop a theoretical framework for interpreting how it relates to the more commonly studied aggregate government spending multiplier. This framework is useful in interpreting the growing number of studies that attempt to use regional variation to measure the government spending multiplier (e.g., Acconcia, Corsetti, and Simonelli 2011; Chodorow-Reich et al. 2012; Clemens and Miran 2012; Cohen, Coval, and Malloy 2011; Fishback and Kachanovskaya 2010; Serrato and Wingender 2010; Shoag 2010; Wilson 2012). We show that the open economy relative multiplier is a sharp diagnostic tool in distinguishing among alternative macroeconomic models. The closed economy aggregate multiplier is highly sensitive to how aggressively monetary and tax policy “lean against the wind” in response to a government spending shock, with the multiplier being larger if policy is more accommodative. In contrast, since the open economy relative multiplier focuses on relative changes in government spending and output, these aggregate factors are “differenced out,” allowing for much sharper theoretical predictions. We show that our estimates are much more consistent with New Keynesian models in which “aggregate demand” shocks—such as government spending shocks—have potentially large effects on output than they are with the plain-vanilla Neoclassical model. In particular, our results suggest that government spending should have large output multipliers when the economy is in a liquidity trap, i.e., the nominal interest rate hits its lower bound of zero and becomes unresponsive to economic shocks. This scenario is particularly relevant in the context of the near zero nominal interest rates that have prevailed in many countries in recent years.
REFERENCES
Acconcia, Antonio, Giancarlo Corsetti, and Saverio Simonelli. 2011. “Mafia and Public Spending: Evidence on the Fiscal Multiplier from a Quasi-experiment.” Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 8305. Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst. 2005. “Consumption versus Expenditure.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (5): 919–48. Aguiar, Mark, Erik Hurst, and Loukas Karabarbounis. 2013. “Time Use during the Great Recession.” American Economic Review 103 (5): 1664–96. Alesina, Alberto, and Silvia Ardagna. 2010. “Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus Spending.” In Tax Policy and the Economy. Vol. 24, edited by Jeffrey R. Brown, 35–68. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Altig, David, Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jesper Linde. 2011. “Firm-Specific Capital, Nominal Rigidities and the Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (2): 225–47. American Chamber of Commerce Realtors Association. 1995–2006. “ACCRA Historical Cost of Living Index.” http://www.coli.org/StoreHistorical.asp (accessed November 2010). Auerbach, Alan J., and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 1–27. Backus, David K., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E. Kydland. 1994. “Dynamics of the Trade Balance and the Terms of Trade: The J-Curve?” American Economic Review 84 (1): 84–103. Backus, David K., and Gregor W. Smith. 1993. “Consumption and Real Exchange Rates in Dynamic Economies with Non-traded Goods.” Journal of International Economics 35 (3–4): 297–316. Bansal, Ravi, and Amir Yaron. 2004. “Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles.” Journal of Finance 59 (4): 1481–509. Barro, Robert J., and Charles J. Redlick. 2011. “Macroeconomic Effects from Government Purchases and Taxes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 51–102. Bartik, Timothy J. 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies? Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.
790 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King. 1993. “Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium.” American Economic Review 83 (3): 315–34. Benigno, Gianluca, and Pierpaolo Benigno. 2003. “Price Stability in Open Economies.” Review of Economic Studies 70 (4): 743–64. Bilbiie, Florin O. 2011. “Nonseparable Preferences, Frisch Labor Supply, and the Consumption Multiplier of Government Spending: One Solution to a Fiscal Policy Puzzle.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 43 (1): 221–51. Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1329–68. Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1992. “Regional Evolutions.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1): 1–61. Braddon, Derek. 1995. “The Regional Impact of Defense Expenditure.” In Handbook of Defense Economics. Vol. 1, edited by Keith Hartley and Todd Sandler, 491–521. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1969–2006a. “Annual State Personal Income and Employment by State.” United States Department of Commerce (accessed October 2009). Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1966–2006b. “Gross Domestic Product by State.” United States Department of Commerce (accessed October 2009). Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1966–2006a. “Consumer Price Index.” United States Department of Labor (accessed October 2009). Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1966–2006b. “Current Employment Survey.” United States Department of Labor (accessed October 2009). Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas D. M. Fisher. 2004. “Fiscal Shocks and Their Consequences.” Journal of Economic Theory 115 (1): 89–117. Calvo, Guillermo A. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework.” Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3): 383–98. Canova, Fabio, and Evi Pappa. 2007. “Price Differentials in Monetary Unions: The Role of Fiscal Shocks.” Economic Journal 117 (520): 713–37. Chari, V. V., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Ellen R. McGrattan. 2002. “Can Sticky Price Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange Rates?” Review of Economic Studies 69 (3): 533–63. Chetty, Raj, Adam Guren, Day Manoli, and Andrea Weber. 2011. “Are Micro and Macro Labor Supply Elasticities Consistent? A Review of Evidence on the Intensive and Extensive Margins.” American Economic Review 101 (3): 471–75. Chodorow-Reich, Gabriel, Laura Feiveson, Zachary Liscow, and William Gui Woolston. 2012. “Does State Fiscal Relief during Recessions Increase Employment? Evidence from the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (3): 118–45. Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 2011. “When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Journal of Political Economy 119 (1): 78–121. Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans. 2005. “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (1): 1–45. Clarida, Richard, Jordi Galí, and Mark Gertler. 2000. “Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (1): 147–80. Clemens, Jeffrey, and Stephen Miran. 2012. “Fiscal Policy Multipliers on Subnational Government Spending.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2): 46–68. Cochrane, John H. 2005. Asset Pricing. 2nd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Cogan, John F., Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland. 2010. “New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34 (3): 281–95. Cohen, Lauren, Joshua Coval, and Christopher Malloy. 2011. “Do Powerful Politicians Cause Corporate Downsizing?” Journal of Political Economy 119 (6): 1015–60. Corsetti, Giancarlo, Keith Kuester, and Gernot J. Muller. 2011. “Floats, Pegs and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy.” Unpublished. Corsetti, Giancarlo, Andre Meier, and Gernot J. Muller. 2012. “Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals.” Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (4): 878–95. Cragg, John G., and Stephen G. Donald. 1993. “Testing Identifiability and Specification in Instrumental Variable Models.” Econometric Theory 9 (2): 222–40. Davis, Steven J., Prakash Loungani, and Ramamohan Mahidhara. 1997. “Regional Labor Fluctuations: Oil Shocks, Military Spending, and other Driving Forces.” Unpublished. Del Negro, Marco. 1998a. “Aggregate Risk Sharing Across US States and Across European Countries.” Unpublished.
Vol. 104 No. 3 Nakamura aNd SteiNSSoN: FiScal StimuluS iN a moNetary uNioN 791 Del Negro, Marco. 1998b. “Aggregate Risk Sharing Across US States and Across European Countries: Dataset.” Unpublished. Department of Defense. 1966–2006. “Procurement Reports and Data Files for Download, 1966–2006.” http://siadapp.dmdc.osd.mil/procurement/Procurement.html (accessed October 2009). Drautzburg, Thorsten, and Harald Uhlig. 2011. “Fiscal Stimulus and Distortionary Taxation.” Unpublished. Edelberg, Wendy, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jonas D. M. Fisher. 1999. “Understanding the Effects of a Shock to Government Purchases.” Review of Economic Dynamics 2 (1): 166–206. Eggertsson, Gauti B. 2010. “What Fiscal Policy is Effective at Zero Interest Rates?” Unpublished. Eichenbaum, Martin, and Jonas D. M. Fisher. 2007. “Estimating the Frequency of Price Re-optimization in Calvo-Style Models.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (7): 2032–47. Farhi, Emmanuel, and Ivan Werning. 2012. “Fiscal Multipliers: Liquidity Traps and Currency Unions.” Unpublished. Federal Reserve Economic Data. 1966–2006a. “Federal Funds Rate.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (accessed March 2011). Federal Reserve Economic Data. 1966–2006b. “Spot Oil Price: West Texas Intermediate.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (accessed October 2010). Fishback, Price V., William C. Horrace, and Shawn Kantor. 2005. “Did New Deal Grant Programs Stimulate Local Economies: A Study of Federal Grants and Retail Sales during the Great Depression.” Journal of Economic History 65 (1): 36–71. Fishback, Price V., and Valentina Kachanovskaya. 2010. “In Search of the Multiplier for Federal Spending in the States During the New Deal.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 16561. Fisher, Jonas D. M., and Ryan Peters. 2010. “Using Stock Returns to Identify Government Spending Shocks.” Economic Journal 120 (544): 414–36. Galí, Jordi, J. David López-Salido, and Javier Valles. 2007. “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (1): 227–70. Galí, Jordi, and Tommaso Monacelli. 2008. “Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in Currency Union.” Journal of International Economics 76 (1): 116–32. Gordon, Robert J., and Robert Krenn. 2010. “The End of the Great Depression 1939–41: Policy Contributions and Fiscal Multipliers.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 16380. Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory W. Huffman. 1988. “Investment, Capacity Utilization, and the Real Business Cycle.” American Economic Review 78 (3): 402–17. Gruber, Jonathan. 2006. “A Tax-Based Estimate of the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 11945. Hall, Robert E. 1988. “Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (2): 339–57. Hall, Robert E. 2009. “By How Much Does GDP Rise If the Government Buys More Output?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 183–231. Hillberry, Russell, and David Hummels. 2003. “Intranational Home Bias: Some Explanations.” Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (4): 1089–92. Hooker, Mark A., and Michael M. Knetter. 1997. “The Effects of Military Spending on Economic Activity: Evidence from State Procurement Spending.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29 (3): 400–21. Ilzetzki, Ethan, Enrique G. Mendoza, and Carlos A. Vegh. 2013. “How Big (Small?) Are Fiscal Multipliers?” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (2): 239–54. Jaimovich, Nir, and Sergio Rebelo. 2009. “Can News about the Future Drive the Business Cycle?” American Economic Review 99 (4): 1097–118. King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, and Sergio T. Rebelo. 1988. “Production, Growth and Business Cycles: I. The Basic Neoclassical Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics 21 (2/3): 195–232. Kraay, Aart. 2012. “How Large Is the Government Spending Multiplier? Evidence from World Bank Lending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (2): 829–87. Mertens, Karel, and Morten O. Ravn. 2010. “Fiscal Policy in an Expectations Driven Liquidity Trap.” Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper 7931. Mintz, Alex, ed. 1992. The Political Economy of Military Spending in the United States. New York: Routledge. Monacelli, Tommaso, and Roberto Perotti. 2008. “Fiscal Policy, Wealth Effects, and Markups.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14584. Mountford, Andrew, and Harald Uhlig. 2009. “What Are the Effects of Fiscal Policy Shocks?” Journal of Applied Econometrics 24 (6): 960–92. Murtazashvili, Irina, and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge. 2008. “Fixed Effects Instrumental Variables Estimation in Correlated Random Coefficient Panel Data Models.” Journal of Econometrics 142 (1): 539–52.
792 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 2014 Nakamura, Emi, Jón Steinsson. 2014. “Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evidence from US Regions: Dataset.” American Economic Review. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.3.753. Nakamura, Emi, Jón Steinsson, Robert Barro, and Jose Ursua. 2013. “Crises and Recoveries in an Empirical Model of Consumption Disasters.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5 (3): 35–74. Nekarda, Christopher J., and Valerie A. Ramey. 2011. “Industry Evidence on the Effects of Government Spending.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (1): 36–59. Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux.” Journal of Political Economy 103 (3): 624–60. Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2005. “Global Current Account Imbalances and Exchange Rate Adjustments.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 67–123. Ohanian, Lee E. 1997. “The Macroeconomic Effects of War Finance in the United States: World War II and the Korean War.” American Economic Review 87 (1): 23–40. Parsley, David C., and Shang-Jin Wei. 1996. “Convergence to the Law of One Price without Trade Barriers or Currency Fluctuations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (4): 1211–36. Perotti, Roberto. 2008. “In Search of the Transmission Mechanism of Fiscal Policy.” In National Bureau of Economic Research Annual 2007. Vol. 22, edited by Daron Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff, and Michael Woodford, 169–226. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Ramey, Valerie A. 2011. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 1–50. Ramey, Valerie A., and Matthew D. Shapiro. 1998. “Costly Capital Reallocation and the Effects of Government Spending.” Carnegie–Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48 (1): 145–94. Romer, Christina, and Jared Bernstein. 2009. “The Job Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Plan.” Washington, DC: Council of Economic Advisers. Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe. 2012. “What’s News in Business Cycles.” Econometrica 80 (6): 2733–64. Serrato, Juan Carlos Suarez, and Philippe Wingender. 2010. “Estimating Local Fiscal Multipliers.” Unpublished. Shoag, Daniel. 2010. “The Impact of Government Spending Shocks: Evidence on the Multiplier from State Pension Plan Returns.” Unpublished. Sims, Christopher A. 2001. “Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models.” Computational Economics 20 (1–2): 1–20. Stock, James H., Jonathan H. Wright, and Motohiro Yogo. 2002. “A Survey of Weak Instruments and Weak Identification in Generalized Method of Moments.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20 (4): 518–29. Stock, James H., and Motohiro Yogo. 2005. “Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression.” In Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, edited by Donald W.K. Andrews and James H. Stock, 80–108. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Taylor, John B. 1993. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1): 195–214. Taylor, John B. 1999. “Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics. Vol. 1, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 1009–50. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland. US Census Bureau. 1963–1983. Current Industrial Reports. MA-175, Shipments of Defense-Oriented Industries. Washington, DC: United States Department of Commerce. US Census Bureau. 1966–2006. “Population by State.” United States Department of Commerce (accessed October 2009). Werning, Ivan. 2012. “Managing a Liquidity Trap: Monetary and Fiscal Policy.” Unpublished. Wilson, Daniel J. 2012. “Fiscal Spending Jobs Multipliers: Evidence from the 2009 American Recovery and Reinvestment Act.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (3): 251–82. Woodford, Mike. 2003. Interest and Prices. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Woodford, Michael. 2005. “Firm-Specific Capital and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve.” International Journal of Central Banking 1 (2): 1–46. Woodford, Michael. 2011. “Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 3 (1): 1–35.
0 件のコメント:
コメントを投稿