ページ

月曜日, 8月 05, 2019

#32:548 MMT, The Euro and The Greatest Prediction of theLast20YearsPosted on July 8, 2012 by Stephanie Kelton By L. Randall Wray


#32:548 MMT, The Euro and The Greatest Prediction of the Last 20 Years Posted on July 8, 2012 by Stephanie Kelton By L. Randall Wray


MMTerたちは1998年にユーロの失敗を予見していた
ケルトン教授も来日講演で紹介していた

#22:358
#23:367
#31:518
#32:548☆

Mosler 1998/5/5









    MMT Can Describe Any of These

        Fixed peg, against:
         - single currency
         -basket of
         currencies
Currency union           Crawling peg  Crawling broad band  Pure float

        ←Fixed     Intermediate regimes   Flexible→

Currency board          Crawling narrow band  Managed float
Dollarisation
        Pegged within bands,
         against:
        - single currency
        - basket of currencies

         MMTはこれらのどれでも記述できます

   に対して固定ペグ:
   - 単一通貨  
    のバスケット
     通貨
通貨ユニオン  クロールペッグ   クロールブロードバンド  ピュアフロート

←固定   中級政権    フレキシブル→

通貨ボード      クロールナローバンド    マネージドフロート
ドルラリゼーション 

   バンド内に釘付け 
   に対して:
   - 単一通貨
    - 通貨のバスケット



crawling peg system

managed float system 管理変動相場制
管理された変動相場制(Managed Floating


MMT Can Describe Any of These

Fixed peg, against:
- single currency
-basket of
currencies
Currency union
Crawling peg
Crawling broad band
Pure float
Intermediate regimes
Fixed
Flexible
Crawling narrow band
Managed float
Pegged within bands,
against:
- single currency
- basket of currencies
Currency board
Dollarisation

MMTはこれらのどれでも記述できます
に対して固定ペグ:
- 単一通貨
のバスケット
通貨
通貨ユニオン
クロールペグ
クロールブロードバンド
純フロート
中期体制
一定
フレキシブル
クロールナローバンド
管理フロート
バンド内に釘付け
に対して:
- 単一通貨
 - 通貨のバスケット
通貨ボード
ドルラリゼーション

井澤論考:
IMFによる為替相場制度の分類改訂について
47
2 新分類の変更点
IMF による為替相場制度の新·旧分類を表1に対比している。
かっこ内は,
2008年4月
末時点の旧分類に基づく加盟国の数と2009年4月末時点の新分類に基づく加盟国の数である。
新·旧分類を対比すると, no separate legal tender と currency board について変更はないが,
other conventional pegged arrangements は, conventional peg とstabilized arrangement に細
分されている。 pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands と crawling peg は変わっていな
いが, crawling band がなくなって crawl-like arrangement が新たにできている。managed float
と independently float がなくなり, floating と free floating に分けられ, 以上のどれにも該当
しない「その他」として other managed arrangement が設けられている。新分類の各カテゴ
リーを以下で説明する。
1no separate legal tender 外貨が唯推一の法貨として流通する。例えば,ドル化したエクアドルやエルサルバドル,ユーロ化したモンテネグロ。
currency board 国内通貨は外貨建て資産によって裏付けられて発行され,固定レート。
2
例えば,アルゼンチンはこのカレンシーボードを採用していたが, 2001年12月の通貨危
機により変動相場制に移行し,新分類では floating に分類されている。
香港はドルのカ
レンシーボード,エストニアとリトアニアはユーロのカレンシーボード。
外貨ないし通貨バスケットにフォーマルに de jure ペッグ。アンカー
conventional peg
3
通貨ないしバスケットのウェイトは公表されるか, IMF に通知されなければならない。
為替レートは少なくとも6ヵ月間に中心レートの上下±1%(マージンでは2%)の変
動幅でなければならない。
為替レートは少なくとも6ヵ月間2%のマージン内にあり,結
stabilized arrangement
4
果として安定していることが確証されなければならない。
指標の変化に応じて固定された率で為替レートが少しずつ調整される。

crawling peg調整ルールや予め決められた率は公表されているか, IMF に通知されなければならな
い。
6 crawl-like arrangement
少なくとも6ヵ月間トレンドに対して2%のマージン内になけ
ればならない。為替レートが単調に減価(ないし増価)しているならば,少なくとも1
%の変化率(年率)であること。エチオピアのみ該当。
7pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands
固定された中心レートに対して上下±1%より広い変動幅で,
中心レートとバンドの幅は公表されるか, IMFに通知されなけ
ればならない。例えば, ERM II を採用しているデンマークはユーロに対して de jure
では±2.25%,
ラトビアは de jure では±15%であるが,実際の変動が土1%以下
であ
第201巻
第 4 号
48
ったためか, conventional peg
に分類されている。
floating 為替レートは主として市場で決定されるが,特定水準の為替レートをターゲ
8
ットにしない為替介入によって変化率を抑え過度な変動を避けることが
ある。
為替介入は例外的な場合のみで, 6ヵ月間に最大3回に限られ,
各回は
free floating
9
せいぜい3営業日であること。介入データがIMF スタッフに利用可能でないならば,
floating となる。
以上のどれにも該当しない場合にはこの「その他」に分類
other managed arrangement
10
される。
2008年4月末から2009年 4月末までの1年間にいくつかの国で為替相場制度が実際に変更
している。例えば,スロバキアは2009年1月よりユーロに加盟したので, ERM II
を含む
pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands (いわゆる ERM II) から free floating になって
いる。欧州中央銀行はユーロの為替相場について域外通貨に対して介入をせずに市場に委ね
るフロート制であるからである。
日本は, 2004年3月16日の円売り·ドル買い介入を最後にその後一度も介入を行っていな
いので, free floating に分類されているのは適当であるが,大規模な介入をしていた時期で
も independently floating に分類されていたのは疑問であった。新分類でより数値化されて
客観的になったといえる。
中国は,
2005年7月21日夜に通貨
バスケットを参考に調整した管理フロート制に移行
する
と公表したが,その後の人民元レートの推移をみると,ドルに対して徐々に切り上げていく,
いわゆる crawling band のような動きを示していたが, 2008年夏からはドルペッグ(固定)
に回帰している。2008年 4月末には旧分類で crawling band であるが, 2009年 4月末には新
分類で stabilized arrangement になっている。
2008年4月末時点の旧分類を新分類で遡及して修正した場合,それぞれの為替
また,
相場
制度を採用する国の数は,以下のようになる。なお, Annual Report
(2009, Table 12) と
Habermeier et al. (2009, p. 4. Table 1)
には集計ミスが見られるため,
筆者自身が作成した。
hard pegs
1 no separate legal tender (10)
2 currency board (13)
soft pegs
3 conventional peg (44)
4 stabilized arrangement (24)




The Launching of the Euro, Proceedings of “A Conference on the European Economic and Monetary Union,” Annandale-on-Hudson, N.Y.: The Bard Center, 1999


This is from a symposium Mat organized in 1998 (published in 1999 in the Eastern Economic Journal) that included a paper by Jan Kregel and a co-authored paper by Goodhart. Warren then organized a London conference in 1998 and Bard College published a collection of papers to coincide with the “launch” of the Euro. Here are a couple of quotes from that 1999 book (The Launching of the Euro, Proceedings of “A Conference on the European Economic and Monetary Union,” Annandale-on-Hudson, N.Y.: The Bard Center, 1999). First, from Warren:
…market forces can demand procyclical fiscal policy during a recession.  Without a higher fiscal authority such as the European Central Bank standing by with counter-cyclical capability and not subject to investor preferences, a severe downward spiral can result, with member nation insolvency at least a technical possibility. At that point, and probably much sooner, I’m certain that the ECB would step out of its Maastricht constraints and take action…. The question today is, if France wants to bail out Credit Lyonnais, or if Italy decides to run a higher budget up, it can’t just do it by decree. You actually have to go out and have investors buy your debts and fund them.

これは、Jan Kregelによる論文とGoodhartによる共著論文を含む、1998年に組織されたシンポジウムMat(1999年にEastern Economic Journalに発表された)からのものです。その後ウォーレンは1998年にロンドンでの会議を開催し、バードカレッジはユーロの「立ち上げ」に合わせて論文集を発表しました。これは1999年の本からの引用です(The Launch of the Euro、 『欧州経済通貨同盟会議』、Annandale-on-Hudson、ニューヨーク:The Bard Center、1999)。まず、ウォーレンから:

…市場の力は不況の間に循環的財政政策を要求することができます。欧州中央銀行のようなより高い財政当局が反循環的な能力で待機し、投資家の選択に左右されなければ、深刻な下方スパイラルが起こり、加盟国の倒産は少なくとも技術的な可能性がある。その時点で、そしておそらくもっと早く、ECBがマーストリヒトの制約から脱して行動を起こすと確信しています…。今日の問題は、フランスがCredit Lyonnaisを救済したいのであれば、あるいはイタリアがより高い予算を実行することを決定したのであれば、それは法令によってそれをすることができないことです。あなたは実際に出かけて、投資家にあなたの借金を買ってもらう必要があります。

MMT, The Euro and The Greatest Prediction of the Last 20 Years

Lest you think NEP is tooting its own hyperbolic horn a bit too much, I borrowed the title of this post from a 2011 piece written by someone who is currently hostile to MMT even though he acknowledges its predictive accuracy.
(I’ll send 5 Buckaroos to the first person who can identify the author! Sorry, UMKC students are not eligible—they have to work an hour for each Buckaroo to pay their taxes.)
The author of that original piece went on to provide some proof for the case he was trying to make.
Being right matters.  This isn’t emphasized quite enough in the finance world and in economics in general.  Too often, bad theory has led to bad predictions which has helped contribute to bad policy.  While MMT remains a heterodox economic school that has been largely shunned by mainstream economists, the modern proponents have an awfully good track record in predicting highly complex economic events… In the last few years, the Euro crisis has proven a remarkably complex and persistent event.  And no school of thought so succinctly predicted the precise cause and effect, as the MMT school did.  These predictions were not vague or general in any manner.  In reading the research from MMTers at the time of the Euro’s inception, their predictions are almost eerily prescient.  They broke down an entire monetary system and described exactly why its construction would lead to financial crisis if the union did not evolve.
You see, he tooted the NEP horn for us. As evidence he selected some juicy quotes:
In his must read book “Understanding Modern Money” Randall Wray described (in 1998) the same dynamic that led to the crisis in the EMU: ‘Under the EMU, monetary policy is supposed to be divorced from fiscal policy, with a great degree of monetary policy independence in order to focus on the primary objective of price stability.  Fiscal policy, in turn will be tightly constrained by criteria which dictate maximum deficit to GDP and debt to deficit ratios.  Most importantly, as Goodhart recognizes, this will be the world’s first modern experiment on a wide scale that would attempt to break the link between a government and its currency. …As currently designed, the EMU will have a central bank (the ECB) but it will not have any fiscal branch.  This would be much like a US which operated with a Fed, but with only individual state treasuries.  It will be as if each EMU member country were to attempt to operate fiscal policy in a foreign currency; deficit spending will require borrowing in that foreign currency according to the dictates of private markets.’
In 2002, Stephanie Kelton (then Stephanie Bell) was even more specific in describing the funding crisis that would inevitably ensue in the region: ‘Countries that wish to compete for benchmark status, or to improve the terms on which they borrow, will have an incentive to reduce fiscal deficits or strive for budget surpluses. In countries where this becomes the overriding policy objective, we should not be surprised to find relatively little attention paid to the stabilization of output and employment. In contrast, countries that attempt to eschew the principles of “sound” finance may find that they are unable to run large, counter-cyclical deficits, as lenders refuse to provide sufficient credit on desirable terms. Until something is done to enable member states to avert these financial constraints (e.g. political union and the establishment of a federal (EU) budget or the establishment of a new lending institution, designed to aid member states in pursuing a broad set of policy objectives), the prospects for stabilization in the Eurozone appear grim.’” (emphasis in the original blog)
In 2001 Warren Mosler described the liquidity crisis that the Euro would lead to: ‘Water freezes at 0 degrees C.  But very still water can be cooled well below that and stay liquid until a catalyst, such as a sudden breeze, causes it to instantly solidify.  Likewise, the conditions for a national liquidity crisis that will shut down the euro-12’s monetary system are firmly in place.  All that is required is an economic slowdown that threatens either tax revenues or the capital of the banking system… A prosperous financial future belongs to those who respect the dynamics and are prepared for the day of reckoning.  History and logic dictate that the credit sensitive euro-12 national governments and banking system will be tested.  The market’s arrows will inflict an initially narrow liquidity crisis, which will immediately infect and rapidly arrest the entire euro payments system.  Only the inevitable, currently prohibited, direct intervention of the ECB will be capable of performing the resurrection, and from the ashes of that fallen flaming star an immortal sovereign currency will no doubt emerge.’
Wow. Pretty much hit that nail on the head. For completeness let me add a few more comments. MMT got its start as “Soft Currency Economics”, the title of Warren Mosler’s 1995 monograph, and what could be called the first Modern Money conference was held at Bretton Woods in 1996, sponsored and organized by Warren with assistance from Pavlina Tcherneva (who was Mat Forstater’s undergrad at the time).
Shortly thereafter we created the Center for Full Employment and Price Stability headquartered at the Levy Economics Institute and funded by Warren. I had already started writing Understanding Modern Money (in 1995 as I recall) but was finishing it up at Levy in 1997 and circulating it among Warren, Mat Forstater, Stephanie Kelton (then Bell), Pavlina Tcherneva, and Wynne Godley (among others) for discussion (Scott Fullwiler soon also got a copy of the draft). To be sure, my book mostly concerned a sovereign currency-issuing government but at the time we were of course aware of the soon-to-be-launched Euro experiment.  The first paper devoted to the problems with the Euro that we read was by Charles Goodhart (who was at that first meeting at Bretton Woods); we read a draft in 1996 (“The Two Concepts of Money and the Future of Europe”) and a version was published in 1997 (“One Government, One Money” appeared in The Prospect in March 1997).
At Levy we discussed these problems and Wynne wrote an excellent editorial, in 1997 after we had all settled at Levy: “Curried Emu: the meal that fails to nourish”. (Interesting tidbit: the author whose title I stole for this essay quotes Wynne’s article but inaccurately dates it as 1992. A footnote then says the date was “corrected” to 1992. But the actual date was 1997 so presumably the author “corrected” the correct date to an incorrect prior date. To be sure, Wynne did write an amazingly prescient piece in 1992, titled “Maastricht and All That“. However, the 1992 criticism of the Euro project is not as specific as the argument Wynne made in the quote from the 1997 article. That is not surprising since the details were not well-understood about a project that would not launch until the end of the decade. Why the author has got the dates all mixed up is unknown.)
Here’s another great quote, from Mat Forstater, written in 1998 and published a year later:
Under the EMU, if investors are at all hesitant about any one member’s debt, they can buy another member’s debt without incurring currency risk, since there is no exchange rate variability among the currencies of member countries. Because member nations are now dependent on investors for funding their expenditure, failure to attract investors results in an inability to spend. Furthermore, should a member’s revenues fail to keep pace with expenditures due to an economic slowdown, investors will likely demand a budget that is balanced, most likely through spending cuts. In other words, market forces can demand pro-cyclical fiscal policy during a recession, compounding recessionary influences…. Even if there were no imposed limits on countries’ deficits and national debts, the structure of the EMU makes it nearly impossible for a country to enact a counter-cyclical fiscal policy even if there were the political will. This is because, by giving up their national monetary sovereignty, countries are no longer able to conduct coordinated fiscal and monetary policy, essential for a comprehensive and effective remedy to periodic demand crises. Why would countries voluntarily sacrifice the ability to conduct a coordinated macroeconomic policy, especially at a time when official unemployment rates are in double digits and there are clear deflationary pressures?
This is from a symposium Mat organized in 1998 (published in 1999 in the Eastern Economic Journal) that included a paper by Jan Kregel and a co-authored paper by Goodhart. Warren then organized a London conference in 1998 and Bard College published a collection of papers to coincide with the “launch” of the Euro. Here are a couple of quotes from that 1999 book (The Launching of the Euro, Proceedings of “A Conference on the European Economic and Monetary Union,” Annandale-on-Hudson, N.Y.: The Bard Center, 1999). First, from Warren:
…market forces can demand procyclical fiscal policy during a recession.  Without a higher fiscal authority such as the European Central Bank standing by with counter-cyclical capability and not subject to investor preferences, a severe downward spiral can result, with member nation insolvency at least a technical possibility. At that point, and probably much sooner, I’m certain that the ECB would step out of its Maastricht constraints and take action…. The question today is, if France wants to bail out Credit Lyonnais, or if Italy decides to run a higher budget up, it can’t just do it by decree. You actually have to go out and have investors buy your debts and fund them.
Here’s Jan Kregel from the same book:
Germany appears to have adopted a policy of controlling the growth of nominal wages at a rate that is below its domestic productivity growth. German unit labor costs have been falling …. If Germany does in fact manage, as it seems to have been doing for about two years, to continue to decrease its unit labor costs at 5 percent — that is, at rates that are substantially below those in the other European countries, with no longer a possibility, as has been the case in the past, for the deutschemark to revalue relative to the other currencies — this means that if I am a manufacturer or a government in a non-German European country, I am going to experience declining profit margins until I also manage to compress my unit labor costs. Therefore, if there is a risk associated with the EMU’s introduction of a single currency under conditions in which Germany is practicing a policy based on a belief that in absolute terms their wage costs are too high relative to Asia and the United States — not internally, relative to Europe — there will be very strong deflationary pressures on wages in the other European countries, which will produce a risk that is, I would say, now roughly balanced between zero inflation and outright deflation.
Well, that is precisely what Germany did for the next half dozen years—helping to fuel current account deficits on the periphery. And, finally, here’s how Warren concluded the book:
We happen to think that there should be a contingency plan for the ECB should a crisis happen. . . should a crisis occur, we’ll have this little book on the shelf with which to come up with some ideas. Meanwhile, I’m not going to buy any German, French, Italian or Spanish bonds with your money…
It is now no secret that the EMU had no contingency plan, so for the past 5 years has been making up responses as it goes along—always too little, too late, and too ill-informed to resolve the problems created by delinking nations from their currencies.
Finally, Stephanie and Ed Nell teamed up to publish a series of scholarly papers all focused around a 1998 paper by Goodhart that continued his Chartalist critique of the Euro project in his paper titled “The Two Concepts of Money: Implications for the Analysis of Optimal Currency Areas”.  You can still obtain a copy of the Bell/Nell edited volume here. And if that is not yet enough evidence, take a look at Stephanie’s paper from 2002 that correctly foresaw problems with credit default risk.
In order to judge how correct MMT was in its predictions, of course, we have to understand what went wrong in the Eurozone. Our argument was that separating fiscal policy from currency sovereignty would raise questions of solvency that would constrain ability of fiscal policy to expand when necessary. That was the basis of all these arguments: Godley, Goodhart, Bell/Kelton, Forstater, and Wray. But there was an additional angle: how would the crisis begin? Would it be a recession that no individual government could resolve by fiscal stimulus? Would it be chronic current account deficits of some member states (to the benefit of Mercantilists like Germany or the Netherlands)? Or would it be a financial crisis? Well, how about a Trifecta: all three at once?
I think all readers of NEP understand the problems raised by recession—so there is no need to go into that one in detail. As individual nations faced a downturn, their budgets would move sharply to deficits that would rise further above Maastricht criteria; markets would react with higher interest rates that would in turn raise deficits further in a vicious cycle. OK, that happened. And then, of course, we also found out that (Surprise! Surprise!) governments had already been manipulating accounting so their deficits had always been higher than supposed.
NEP readers are also familiar with the current account story—easily understood through the lens of Godley’s sectoral balance approach. The best work in this area has been done by Eric Tymoigne, Daniel Negreiros Conceição, Scott Fullwiler, and especially Rob Parenteau (who has enriched a model introduced by Paul Krugman). I won’t expand on that right now—but a current account deficit must be offset by a combination of a domestic private sector deficit and/or a government deficit. Since these are not sovereign currency issuing governments, private and government deficits can both lead to problems. (To be clear, it is much more than a current account problem, as Rob shows. Any EMU nation can be blown up by its banks even while running a current account surplus. This is the “financialization” or “Money Manager Capitalism” story—probably more than 90% of cross-border finance has nothing to do with the current account, and it was that part of finance that blew up countries like Ireland and Spain. I’ll explain that elsewhere in a response to an entirely confused and specious anti-MMT diatribe by Sergio Cessarato.)
Finally there was the financial crisis angle. So far as I know, Warren Mosler was the first to fully understand this. He was harping on it for as long as I can remember—long before the 2001 article quoted above.
(I have recently become aware of a 1998 paper by P.M. Garber (1998. “Notes on the Role of TARGET in a Stage III Crisis.” Working Paper 6619, Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. June.) that explicated the problems created by the clearing mechanism. I covered that over in my GLF blog two weeks ago. A troll responded that MMT had never before paid any attention to the EMU, and (wrongly) cited the “1992” article by Godley as evidence that we simply stole the idea from him.)
But Warren had long argued that a very likely path to crisis would come from a bank failure. With no equivalent to Washington to come to the rescue, each individual nation would have to bail out its own banks. That would add to government debt, cause interest rates to spike, and lead to a run out of banks that could not be stopped. Except by the center—the ECB—which was not supposed to do anything of the sort.
Hello!?! That’s where we are, folks.
Judge for yourselves. Greatest prediction of the past 20 years? Probably not. But certainly our understanding of how “modern money” works helped us to see the underlying problems. Our main claim is now commonplace—almost no commentator now fails to refer to the problems created by separating fiscal policy from the currency. When we wrote this back in 1997-99 at the launch of the misguided experiment, we were ridiculed as fringe nay-sayers. We’re still ridiculed as fringe, of course, even though our main argument is now as mainstream as it can get.
Here are just a few of the mainstream predictions about the Euro also from that little 1999 book, The Launching of the Euro. We knew they were wrong at the time; they are hilarious in retrospect. One wonders where these people are now? Do rotten predictions by mainstreamers ever get punished, or are all their pronouncements—no matter how silly—always one way bets to success?
Let me come to grips with the problem of a debt crisis. A debt crisis may happen, but the EMU does not make it more likely to occur than before. I am even inclined to think that the EMU makes a debt crisis less likely.(Cesar Molinas, First Vice President and Head of European Fixed Income and Research, Merrill Lynch)
What if there is an unusually strong downturn? In that case, the stability pact allows deficits above 3 percent. So there is an escape clause in the stability pact….In such a case, I think spreads would probably widen…However, I think the main market impact probably is an under performance of EMU-bloc governments as a whole, rather than a dramatic intra-EMU spread widening. (Gunther Thurman, Managing Director, Salomon Smith Barney)
Certainly, among most of the major countries in Euroland, there is a very great similarity of economic structures, and the economic cycles are in most cases remarkably coexistent. This suggests that one size fits all. It won’t create a serious problem as has sometimes been suggested.  (Norman Williams, European Economist, Barclays Capital)
It is not that the whole fiscal picture in Europe is going to collapse.  We can “short” something and “long” something and have lots of up-and-down movements. What’s going to go wrong is indeed that nothing is going to go wrong from our point of view.  (Jan Loeys, Managing Director, JPMorgan)
Nothing wrong, indeed!  

#32:548
During the nrst decade of the Eurozone,many critics focused on the policy of the European Central Bank(ECB),arguing thatits monetary policy was too Jght Others argued that the Maastttcht⊂riteria were too aghtWhile both criticisms had some validity they missed the main problem:ltaly and Other countries had become theequivalent of a State such as Louisiana orん輛ssissippl in the∪nited States or NSW or∨ictoria in Australia,whichdo not issue their ovvn currencies The difFerence′howeveぅbetween these States and the Member States oftheEurozoneisthatthelatterdonotenjoythebenentofafederalgovernmentthatcanmakemonetarytransferstostates ln crlsls.Given the EM∪structure′individual Eurozone members faced t、vo problems:・ NA/hen there vvas a deep recession′their nscal pOsitions would automatica‖y llnove into deep dencit llne prOb´lem would not bethe A/1aastricht Criteria ρθr sθ′since alrnost a‖euro nations persistently violated those criteriaover the decade before the crisis which began in 2009,but rather that markets would raise risk prenlia on theirdebt,M/hich occurred in 2008.This caused interest rates to rise sharply in a manner that reinforced the rise indencitsin a vicious cycle.hA/ith no nscalauthority to come to theirrescue,Eurozone countries had to rely on thecharity ofthe ECB to keep theirinterest rates doMノn.VVith the ECB operating underthe thumb Ofthe GermanBundesbank,that was always unlikely・ lndividuai nations were responsible for their o、へ/n banking systems,but they did not have the nscal capacity tobail then1 0ut.Again,there was no equivalent to a nscal authority in Brussels to assist the national governmentsthat Ⅵ/ere burdened by debt run up by private banks,debt that could eas‖y be rnore than preva‖ing govern´mentspending or even GDR30ne of the goals ofintegration was to free up labour and capital ЯOws by remOving barriers so that factors ofproduction could cross borders.Whatisimportant for our discussion is that this alsO enabled Eurozone banks tobuy assets and issue liab‖ities a‖over the rnonetary unionFurtheらthe deregulation and de´supervision of banking outlined in the Basel Accords a‖owed banksto under´take the same sOrt ofrisky schemes that hA/a‖Streett banks had pursued.The result、vasthat by 2007 the E∪hadbuilt up a real estate bubb!e that vvas allanost identicalin size to the∪S's bubble,and again this waslargely unrec″ognised by mainstream econon■sts who held faith in the、へ/isdonl of`free marketstThe irish banks had ramped up theirlending across Europe′growing their liab‖ities to rnuitiples oflrish GDRThen′when their bets went bad,the lrish government had tO ba‖them out′boosting nscal dencits and raisinggovernment debtto uncharted territory Again′this was a design feature ofthe EA/1U and the E∪more genera‖yl soit was notiuSt euro banks that engaged in excessivelending.This also Occurred in!celand and the∪K ltis probablethat this was not fbreseen′fbr the reasOns discussed above.A/1ainstreanl economists had little understanding of6nancial markets because their theory and rnodeis had no roonn fOr the reallA/Orld connplexity of rnodern ttnanceAlso important to the continuing crisis in the Eurozone,、vhich actua‖y sank deeperinto crisis as the∪S and∪K recovered,was the ab‖ity of bank depositors to costlessly shift euro deposits from one bank to anotheりany´where in the EA/1∪.This is possible due to the so´ca‖ed Target 2 fac‖ity.For exannple,any depositor of a Spanishbank can mOve depOsits to a German bank.Such a shift requires that the central bank Of Spain obtain reservesthat are then credited to the central bank of Germany.lf deposits tend to lo、へ/from the periphery natiOns,theircentralbanksgoeverrnoredeeplyintodebttotheECBtoobtainreservesthataccumulateintheaccountsofthestrongest nations'central banks,such asthe German Bundesbank.As the crisis spread among pettphery nations,the rTrolka'(COnsisting ofthe lMR the ECB and the EuropeanCommission)demanded austenty as a condition for nnancial assistance Yet the only way any indi宙dual statecould grow in the face Of austerity would be by operating a rbeggar thy neighbour'mercantinst p。‖cy to suckdemand out ofthe otherstates.This was done by achieving a pOsitive trade balance,that is,with exports exceed´Ing lmports.ExpOrting earns reterve credits for the natiOnt central bank,and creates income and,obs fOr the dOmes‐tic economy.Germany exce‖ed at that.So,vvh‖e the whole idea behind unincation was to prevent the typeof unneighbourly behaviour that had led to twO hA/orld Wars within Europe′the construction of the EA/1U llvasguaranteed to pronnote it.The EA/1∪revvarded sel「interested behaviour by any men∩ber wi‖ing to pursue it,andCermany reaped most ofthe rewards

ユーロ圏の最初の10年間で、多くの批評家は、欧州中央銀行(ECB)の政策に焦点を当て、金融政策はあまりにも厳しすぎると主張した。他の者は、Maastttcht裁判所は厳しすぎると主張した。ルイジアナ州やオーストラリアのNSW州やビクトリア州のような他の国々は、これらの州と他の国との間で異なる通貨を発行することができませんでした。 EMの「構造」個々のユーロ圏メンバーが以下のような問題に直面したとする。・NA /あちこちで深刻な後退を招くとは限らず、深刻な不況に陥ることはない。その前の10年間で、ヨーロッパの国々はこれらの基準に永続的に違反していました。 2009年に始まったリスクが、むしろ市場がリスクプレンリアを引き上げる可能性があるため、2008年にはM / hが発生しました。これは、悪循環の中での上昇を加速させる形で金利を急上昇させました。そのため、ユーロ圏諸国はECBの利子率を維持するためにECBの信憑性に頼らざるを得なかった。それは、常にそうではなかった・インドの銀行システムに対して責任を負っていた。しかし、ブリュッセルには、民間銀行による債務返済によって負担される国民政府を支援するための政府当局に相当するものは存在しませんでした。統合の目的の一つとして政府や政府がGDR30を使うのは、生産の要素が国境を越えられるように、障壁を取り除くことによって労働力と資本を解放することであった。また、ユーロ圏の銀行は、金融組合に対する資産の購入と負債の発行を可能にしました。さらに、バーゼル協定で概説されている銀行の規制緩和および廃止のために、以下の同じスキームを採用しました。その結果、2007年までにE社は、S社のバブルとほぼ同じ大きさの不動産バブルを構築しましたが、これもまた、主流のeconon社が信じることを認めなかった。アイルランドの銀行は、ヨーロッパ全土でGDRの利害関係を擁護するために債務を増やし、その結果、アイルランド政府は、政府の債務を急増させ、政府の債務を不当な領土に増やすことがありました。これもまたEA / 1Uの設計上の特徴であり、Eより一般的な訴訟は、過度の貸付を行っているユーロ銀行ではありませんでした。彼らの理論や理論が複雑であるとは限らないため、ユーロ圏の継続的な危機にとって重要なことではなく、実際の経済学者たちは金融市場についてほとんど理解していなかった。 「S」と「K」が回復したのは、銀行預金者がユーロ預金を1つの銀行から別の場所にEA / 1のどこかに無駄にシフトさせることができなかったことです。たとえば、スペインの銀行のどの預金者もドイツの銀行に預金を移すことができます。そのようなシフトでは、スペインの中央銀行がリザーブを取得し、その後ドイツの中央銀行に貸方記入される必要があります。そのような中央銀行は、ドイツ連邦共和国のような最も過激な国の中央銀行に積み立てるための貯蓄を得るために使われています。しかしECBとEuropeanCommissionは、緊縮財政に直面して成長する可能性がある唯一の方法は、他の諸国からの非難を排除するための唯一の方法であろう。これは、潜在的な貿易収支を達成することによって、すなわち輸出が「国内輸出を上回る」ことによって達成され、国民の中央銀行に対する信用を獲得し、所得を創出し、その点でドイツ経済を追い越している。ですから、unkationの背後にある全体的な考えは、ヨーロッパ内で2度の戦争につながっていた不注意な行動のタイプを防ぐことであり、EA / 1Uの構築はそれを補足することを保証しました。追求しようとしている男性による行動。そして、ほとんどの報酬を享受した。



1 件のコメント:


  1. yoji2020年10月30日 23:54
    2020/10/3
    「MMTの真髄を知る」第2回
    https://youtu.be/iiROxIsMiL0

    17:00

    返信削除

    yoji2020年10月30日 23:59
    https://i.imgur.com/Iw6Ncgx.jpg

    返信削除

    返信削除