The bourgeoisie, during its rule of scarce one hundred years, has created more massive and more colossal productive forces than have all preceding generations together. Subjection of Nature’s forces to man, machinery, application of chemistry to industry and agriculture, steam-navigation, railways, electric telegraphs, clearing of whole continents for cultivation, canalisation of rivers, whole populations conjured out of the ground — what earlier century had even a presentiment that such productive forces slumbered in the lap of social labour?
The weapons with which the bourgeoisie felled feudalism to the ground are now turned against the bourgeoisie itself.
But not only has the bourgeoisie forged the weapons that bring death to itself; it has also called into existence the men who are to wield those weapons — the modern working class — the proletarians.
AIMN: How does MMT circumvent further unemployment and create jobs?
Mitchell: First you have to understand why unemployment arises. The Neo-liberal ideology that supports this harassment of the unemployed through this unemployment ‘industry’ has created the narrative and the construction that the cause of unemployment is the individual cause. If the person hasn’t invested in skills earlier in life, has a lackadaisical attitude to life, doesn’t want to work, prefers to live on the dole even though its well below the poverty line, that somehow this is created as some sort of Shangri-la that people aspire to as a life style choice.
The unemployed, who are the victims of systemic failure, are suddenly in the media and therefore in the public eye, as the cause of the problem.
You can’t search for jobs that aren’t there. You can push and shove and harass people to search harder but if there’s only 100 jobs and there’s 120 people chasing them, bad luck! You can rev up people through fear and income support loss but if there’s a shortage of jobs – there’s a shortage of jobs!
If you understand the systemic failure – and when there’s systemic constraints individuals have very little power – one person against the system. Why does the system fail to produce enough jobs? Marx knew the answer, and later in a more acceptable form in the West, so did Keynes.
This is Part 2 (and final) in my discussion about what the financial markets might learn from gaining a Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) understanding. I noted in Part 1 – that the motivation in writing this series was the increased interest being shown by some of the large financial sector entities (investment banks, sovereign funds, etc) in MMT, which is manifesting in the growing speaking invitations I am receiving. This development tells me that our work is gaining traction despite the visceral, knee-jerk attacks from the populist academic type economists (Krugman, Summers, Rogoff, and all the rest that have jumped on their bandwagon) who are trying to save their reputations as their message becomes increasingly vapid. While accepting these invitations raises issues about motivation – they want to make money, I want to educate – these groups are influential in a number of ways. They help to set the pattern of investment (both in real and financial terms), they hire graduates and can thus influence the type of standards deemed acceptable, and they influence government policy. Through education one hopes that these influences help turn the tide away from narrow ‘Gordon Gekko’ type behaviour towards advancing a dialogue and policy structure that improves general well-being. I also hope that it will further create dissonance in the academic sphere to highlight the poverty (fake knowledge) of the mainstream macroeconomic orthodoxy.
There was an article in the Project Syndicate (July 1, 2019) – Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? – written by a Yale economics professor and advisor to Shinzo Abe, that reveals the extent to which the mainstream is becoming paranoid and is failing to understand what MMT is about.
I won’t deal with it in detail because it is not my brief today. But it aims to disabuse readers of the notion that “Japan … [is] … proof that the approach works.”
The approach he refers to is MMT.
Basic flaw. MMT is not an approach. These commentators haven’t even reached the first place in understanding what our work is about.
Mainstream economists have crudely characterised or framed MMT within their own conceptual structure (typically the so-called ‘government budget constraint’ (GBC) framework) and imputed their own language when discussing MMT.
The Project Syndicate author is no exception.
He thinks MMT is about “excessive deficit-financed spending” which “lacks any safeguard”.
He says:
Policymakers who recklessly implement MMT may find, like the sorcerer’s apprentice, that once the policies are set in motion, they will be difficult to stop.
One cannot “implement MMT” – recklessly or otherwise.
One can understand it and use its insights to craft policy interventions that accord with one’s value system (ideology).
The author invokes the image of the – Sorcerer’s Apprentice – a poem by Johann Goethe, to conjure up images of chaos and attempts to associate these images with our work.
But if he understood the poem and its historical context he would realise it is an extremely poor exampl to use.
Goethe, after all, was opposed to the French revolutionaries who overthrew the corrupt monarchy. He didn’t consider the former were capable. The poem in question was written around this time.
Modern bourgeois society, with its relations of production, of exchange and of property, a society that has conjured up such gigantic means of production and of exchange, is like the sorcerer who is no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he has called up by his spells. For many a decade past the history of industry and commerce is but the history of the revolt of modern productive forces against modern conditions of production, against the property relations that are the conditions for the existence of the bourgeois and of its rule. It is enough to mention the commercial crises that by their periodical return put the existence of the entire bourgeois society on its trial, each time more threateningly.
The point is that Goethe was promoting the idea that the master has the wisdom to use his power effectively while the apprentice does not have that skill and should wait his time.
But if that master has failed – then the authority is gone.
Mainstream macroeconomics is not the master and MMT economists are not the apprentices.
The former deliver fake knowledge and all their incantantions cannot alter that fact.
I have made this point before but it is worth repeating because how we construct an argument (framing, concepts, language, etc) is incredibly important and influences how the argument is developed and received.
Mainstream economics starts with the flawed analogy between the household and the sovereign government such that any excess in government spending over taxation receipts has to be ‘financed’ in two ways: (a) by borrowing from the public; and/or (b) by ‘printing money’.
This framing therefore has three quite separate cases in relation to government spending:
1. Governments raise taxes which permit them to spend up to that level.
2. If governments want to spend beyond that level they have to find extra money.
(a) They can borrow the money from the non-government sector (issue debt) which pushes up interest rates (via the defunct loanable funds theory).
(b) They can instruct the central bank to print money and put it into circulation which is inflationary (via the defunct Quantity Theory of Money).
So there are three types of government spending with different impacts depending on the type chosen.
This characterisation is not remotely representative of what happens in the real world in terms of the operations that define transactions between the government and non-government sector.
The GBC framework entered the mainstream literature in the 1960s when it was claimed that government’s had the same constraints as households.
The basic analogy is flawed at its most elemental level. Households must work out the financing before it can spend – it has to earn income, run down savings, sell assets or borrow.
The household cannot spend first.
A currency-issuing government can (must) spend first and ultimately does not have to worry about financing such expenditure.
The mainstream economists see that statement and try to understand it within the flawed GBC framework.
So they interpret fiscal deficits as being typically damaging because they either drive up interest rates and ‘crowd out’ private spending that is sensitive to increases in interest rates or they become inflationary, depending on whether 2(a) or 2(b) is chosen.
And they might read somewhere that MMT economists point out that no debt needs to be issued to accompany a fiscal deficit and they frame that – because they construct everything fiscal within the GBC framework – as being about ‘printing money’.
Then, the GBC logic is applied and so MMT becomes a policy idea that wants the government to vicariously print money which automatically causes accelerating inflation because there will be “too much money chasing too few goods”!
Even the Project Syndicate author acknowledges that the massive fiscal deficits in Japan (and the fact the Bank of Japan has bought significant quantities of government debt) has:
… not generated a much-feared surge in inflation.
Note, the “much-feared” term.
However, he fails to interrogate that proposition in any way choosing to divert attention to a relatively meaningless and well-known fact that in Japan’s case there is a significant difference between gross and net public debt. So what?
Of course, reality is quite different to the way the GBC framework depicts the fiscal options.
There is only one type of government spending – where the relevant government body instructs a banker (usually a central banker) to credit some bank accounts. In some cases, cheques may be sent out but that practice is rapidly declining as the digital world expands its reach.
The inflation risk is embedded in the spending – how it impacts in goods and services markets.
And that risk isn’t particular to public spending. All spending carries the risk of setting of inflation.
In practice, many inflationary episodes have nothing to do with ‘spending’ surges. They arise from supply shocks or corrupt behaviour or cartel behaviour.
Issuing bonds to accompany fiscal deficits does not reduce the inflation risk. The bond purchases reflect an asset portfolio change – the funds were not being spent anyway.
If the bond holders subsequently use the income flows from the interest earned to increase, say, their consumption spending, then the government deficit will likely fall anyway due to the higher level of economic activity and rising tax flows.
If the higher level of activity threatens to push the economy beyond the inflation barrier then there are a series of choices the government can make, including reducing its deficit.
There is no sorcery involved. And no apprentices.
Further, the idea that ‘printing money’ is somehow an option is ridiculous. As noted above, all spending occurs in the same way – crediting bank accounts. No printers are involved.
It is interesting that the Project Syndicate author effectively, by his silence, does not seem to buy the ‘crowding out’ story. His sole focus is on the inflation story, however erroneous his depiction of that causality might be.
He claims that:
Implementing such a policy successfully, however, would demand careful attention to inflationary risks. The current deflationary phase will not last forever. Eventually, supply constraints will be reached, and inflation will return. If the government has been engaging in excessive deficit-financed spending, once inflation is triggered, it could quickly spin out of control.
It could although just to the term “deficit-financed” is GBC language.
The point is that I would challenge the Project Syndicate author to show me where in the extensive MMT literature developed by the core group do we write or say anything that would say fiscal deficits cannot be excessive under some circumstances.
The GBC framework is entrenched in the way economists think about fiscal policy impacts on financial markets and as the Project Syndicate article demonstrates is still resonant.
It is also clear that many players in the financial markets, who have probably been indoctrinated by mainstream macroeconomics programs in one way or another, have historically acted within that framework – to their detriment.
These are the characters that presumably lost in the famous ‘widow maker’ trade on Japanese government bonds.
Here is the history of the 10-year Japanese government bonds from September 24, 1974 to June 28, 2019. On September 28, 1990, the yield on the 10-year bond peaked at 8.105 per cent.
The so-called ‘macro traders’ (those who decide their investment portfolios on the basis of macroeconomic principles and judgements about national politics) rushed in and ‘shorted’ the 10-year bond market.
Why? Because they had drank the ‘kool saké’ of mainstream macroeconomics and believed that the debt position in Japan was unsustainable and as a result yields would have to rise and bond prices fall.
So the short trade was to commit to selling these bonds at some future point in time and hoping at that point in time the spot price would have fallen below the future contract price thus eliciting a profit.
Variations of that theme were evident.
Any portfolio manager that bet on government debt yields rising in any systematic way lost a lot of money in the process.
On June 28, 2019, the 10-year bond was trading at -0.156 per cent, the 25-year at 0.302 per cent and the 40-year at 0.413 per cent.
As yourself what that means about expected inflation rates.
And then think about the fact that currently the Bank of Japan holds more than 40 per cent of Japanese government debt (as a result of its various QE programs) and has purchased most of the available issue since the Abe government came to power.
Mainstream economists consistently predict higher yields will emerge and higher inflation as a result of the Bank’s purchases, which pump reserves into the banking system in return for the debt purchases.
Chasing higher yields via these ‘widowmaker’ trades led to losses because the investment banks etc were engaged in a battle against the Bank of Japan, which is a battle they can never win.
An MMT understanding shows that the sovereign government (central bank and treasury) typically calls the shots over the financial markets.
It sets the rules, has the currency capacity to set yields and volume, and can stop issuing debt altogether if it chooses.
The Bank provides a range of banking services in the US including wealth management.
The short note seeks to:
… make the case for why investors should care about MMT and other potential stimulus measures.
It correctly distinguished MMT from “conventional thinking” (mainstream macroeconomics) where the latter thinks that:
… the ceiling on government spending is a function of tax revenues and the ability to issue debt at a reasonable interest rate.
In contrast, “(u)nder an MMT framework, government deficit spending is only constrained when it stokes unacceptable inflation”, which is sort of correct.
The correct constraint in MMT are the available real resources.
But I liked the term “an MMT framework” – reflecting the lens nature of MMT.
The author also notes that:
Another key difference of MMT compared with conventional economic thinking is that MMT emphasizes the fiscal authority (the federal government) and its ability to influence the economy, unemployment, and inflation versus the monetary authority (the Federal Reserve, or the Fed).
Now this might be conceived as a meagre difference between what the New Keynesian orthodoxy calls the ‘assignment’ problem – which policy tool to assign to what task.
However, our preference for fiscal policy is grounded in our rejection of the GBC literature. In addition, as a progressive MMTer, I object to anti-democratic processes – depoliticisation.
The important point that the Key Private Bank article makes is that:
MMT can provide unique insights into some unconventional policies that have been instituted after the Global Financial Crisis and in other countries such as Japan since the early 2000s. In 2010, many prominent economists were concerned that the Fed’s asset purchase programs (Quantitative Easing, or QE) would stoke currency debasement and inflation. Also, many investors avoided longer-maturity bonds at this time in fear of higher interest rates, and they raised their portfolios’ allocations to real assets that would benefit from higher inflation.
An MMT understanding would have told these investors that the mainstream economists (no matter how prominent they were) were plain wrong and that they would be foregoing profitable investment opportunities if they stayed within that orthodox economics framework.
They were wrong because their framework is wrong. Fake knowledge cannot systematically generate reliable predictions about reality.
It might hit targets occasionally, like a dead clock is correct twice a day! But it will systematically generate predictive errors.
Just look at the forecasting performance of the IMF models!
The Key Private Bank article says that:
With the advantage of hindsight, these fears were unfounded. The US dollar did not collapse, and inflation remained subdued. From an investment perspective, it proved costly to avoid longer-duration bonds and overweight real assets compared with emphasizing assets that benefit from lower inflation and a stronger dollar. An MMT perspective would have provided a different perspective of QE, viewing it as a debt-refinancing operation with limited impacts on inflation and the US dollar. This viewpoint would have been valuable at the time, and it is one potential benefit of understanding the MMT framework. It would have also provided a unique insight on the policies implemented in Japan and Europe.
Well it was available at the time and savvy investors took advantage of it.
The lesson that the Key Private Bank article takes from this is that there is a growing move to reduce reliance on monetary policy for counter-stabilisation and:
… authorities may look to fiscal stimulus that is partially financed by the Fed to increase economic growth.
In that context:
Wealth managers and investors should have a complete view of how this could work and what the potential costs and benefits could be.
The point of the article is that a more “complete view” will not come from mainstream economics. It is clear that MMT economics is a preferred framework to consider and analyse these trends and policy choices.
The Key Private Bank article advises wealth managers to eschew “politically driven views on what should happen”.
These are the views of the dominant paradigm in macroeconomics which make spurious predictions based on a flawed framework.
The sharpest macro investors use these insights on a regular basis. Bridgewater Associates, by some measures the most successful hedge fund of all time, teaches them to its new recruits almost as soon as they walk in the door. Jan Hatzius, chief economist of Goldman Sachs … wrote in a recent client note, MMT “proponents make a couple of points that are both correct and important,” particularly the claim that “private sector deficits are generally more worrisome than public sector deficits.”
Investors armed with these insights knew the British pound would have to leave the European Exchange Rate Mechanism in 1992 and were among those who predicted the euro crisis that began in 2008. They avoided the infamous “widow maker” trade of betting against Japanese government bonds in the 1990s. Bridgewater and Goldman were among the few to realize the danger of rising U.S. household indebtedness during the 2000s, while remaining relatively sanguine about the federal budget deficit.
He notes that the likes of Paul Krugman took the opposite conclusions. For example, in 2003, Krugman “wrote in the New York Times that ‘skyrocketing budget deficits’ would force up interest rates.”
Further “many in finance and academia … [were] … scaremongers warning that “trillion-dollar deficits” and the Fed’s expanding balance sheet would lead to hyperinflation.”
It is clear that by holding out a series of myths as the path to ‘market efficiency’, mainstream macroeconomics leads to actions that actually generate market failure – as the GFC disaster demonstrated in spades.
Leading up to that disaster were all manner of self-congratulatory claims from mainstream economists that the economic cycle had been defeated, that financial market deregulation was delivering untold wealth – until it wasn’t and didn’t.
None of them saw it coming.
None of them saw the disaster that the Eurozone would become.
How much wealth was wiped out in the GFC is hard to assess but you can be sure it was concentrated at the lower end of the distribution.
Fiscal deficits mean more non-government net financial assets
One of the reasons the “sharpest macro investors” didn’t get sucked in by orthodox macroeconomics was that they understood the most basic aggregation in macroeconomics – the relationship between the government (as the currency-issuer) and the non-government (as the currency user).
This relationship is a core starting point for MMT reasoning.
The sectoral balances framework is not new. Nor was it invented, as some think, by British economist Wynne Godley. He certainly deployed it to great effect but the framework was articulated much earlier than his work.
Some of the older Keynesian macroeconomics textbooks from the 1960s and 1970s – contained insights into the sectoral balances – usually as a section in their derivation of the national accounts.
The work of German economist Wolfgang Stützel in the 1950s on – Balances Mechanics – can be considered a precursor to the modern stock-flow consistent reasoning.
After all, the sectoral balances are just a way of viewing the national accounts.
While more recently, the work of Wynne Godley has been important to establishing stock-flow consistency in macroeconomic models, using sectoral flows and their corresponding stocks to advantage, the MMT economists have taken that old framework one step further by distinguishing between vertical and horizontal transactions.
For basic Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) concepts, please read the following introductory suite of blog posts:
Vertical transactions are those between the government sector and non-government sector and they are unique (different to horizontal transactions between entities within the non-government sector) because they alone create or destroy net financial assets in the non-government sector.
A bank loan creates a liability at the same time it creates an asset – nothing net is created.
However, the impacts of vertical transactions show the unique nature of the currency-issuing capacity of the government.
While the starting point – sectoral balances framework – is not new, the MMT perspective or interpretation and utilisation is novel.
What we learn from an MMT understanding is that:
1. A government deficit equals a non-government surplus – dollar-for-dollar. It is not an opinion but an accounting fact.
2. Such a deficit adds net financial assets (wealth) to the non-government sector. Deficits make us richer.
3. A government surplus equals a non-government deficit – dollar-for-dollar.
2. Such a surplus reduces the net financial assets (wealth) to the non-government sector. Surpluses destroy non-government wealth.
You will never learn that in a mainstream economics course. The mainstream economists can claim they knew MMT all along, or that there is nothing new, but you will never read those propositions in a mainstream textbook or hear them in a standard macroeconomics class.
Now that might not be a problem if those insights were trivial.
But, of course, they are not.
Some of the implications are extremely important.
For example, for a nation running a current account deficit (such as Australia – which has been in external deficit of around 3.5 per cent of GDP since the 1970s), the private domestic sector (households and firms) cannot accumulate net financial assets in the currency of issue if the government is running a surplus.
The only way the private domestic sector can save overall when the nation is running an external deficit if the government runs a fiscal deficit and adds net financial assets into the non-government sector.
The implication that then follows is that the only way the private domestic sector can maintain spending growth when the government is running fiscal surpluses is by relying on credit, which, in turn, leads to the increasing stocks of indebtedness and increasing vulnerability.
Ultimately, the balance sheet position of the private domestic sector deteriorates under these conditions to the point that they stop spending and attempt to reduce the precariousness of their balance sheets.
At that point, a recession occurs.
For Australia, the only way the conservative Howard government ran consecutive fiscal surpluses for 10 out of 11 years from 1996 was because household debt skyrocketed and reached unsustainable levels.
If the households had have maintained their historical saving behaviour, the economy would have soon tanked after the first or second year of fiscal drag and the surpluses would have vanished.
A further implication is that austerity become totally counterproductive if the non-government sector spending growth declines and private saving outstrips investment spending.
This desire to increase the non-government net saving requires increased fiscal deficits to avoid recession.
MMT economists have put all those linkages together.
Mainstream macroeconomics is too concentrated on making spurious claims about fiscal deficits – crowding out, inflation, debt burdens on future generations – that they fail to see the most basic role that fiscal policy plays in underpinning the desire to save overall and accumulate net financial assets by the non-government sector.
What can these insights mean for financial markets?
Matthew C. Klein writes that MMT shows:
… that investors cannot own financial assets unless issuers are willing to create them. Creditors cannot save unless debtors borrow. It is therefore impossible for everyone in the world to save by accumulating financial assets at the same time.
This means that corporate profits rise as companies invest, and fall as households, foreigners, and the government save … governments cannot cut their own debts without forcing others to save less or borrow more.
The point is that the smartest operators in the financial markets know this.
Only the less educated financial market players have bought the spin from the mainstream economists that ranges from deficits are typically not desirable to they should be avoided at all costs.
As a consequence, fiscal deficits actually provide more opportunities for financial market investment than surpluses.
This means that financial market operators should never be joining lobbies that proclaim the deficits are bad and should be avoided.
Quite the contrary.
Sovereign Funds
This leads to a consideration of so-called sovereign funds.
I wrote about the Australian version in this blog post – The Future Fund scandal (April 19, 2009).
The Future Fund was created by the Howard government which claimed it would ‘use’ the fiscal surpluses it was generating on the back of the household credit binge in the late 1990s to accumulate a stock of financial assets that would allow it to cover, in the first instance, the so-called ‘unfunded’ superannuation liabilities of public servants.
Its motivation was thus spurious at the outset.
It was claiming that the currency-issuing government would be unable to fund these liabilities as they came due because it would run out of money.
The terminology – Future Fund – was also unfortunate, given that the initiative ultimately undermines our future.
How so?
Essentially, the Future Fund was created using the net funds that were being extracted by the federal government from the non-government sector – spending less than they were taking out in taxation.
So after depriving the non-government sector of net financial assets, the government then used those funds to speculate in financial markets and accumulate financial assets themselves.
But at the same time it was overseeing chronic unemployment, rising underemployment, degenerating public infrastructure, declining educational standards, reduced service standards in the health system, and increased gridlock on our roads due to lack of planning.
At the time, the government could have used the net spending that they put into the Future Fund to offer a Job Guarantee position to all of the unemployed and underemployed for about the next decade at minimum wages.
When that option was presented, the response, among other disparaging remarks, was that there was no fiscal room to do any more on that front than they were doing at the time.
So we had a situation where our elected national government preferred to buy speculative financial assets instead of buying all the labour that is left idle by the private market. They prefer to hold bits of paper that has lost value than putting all this labour to work to develop communities and restore our natural environment.
They also preferred these bits of paper to improving our public infrastructure, making us the best performed education system in the world, reducing hospital queues, and improving public transport etc.
The point is that an MMT understanding shows that the currency-issuing government’s ability to make timely payment in its own currency is never numerically constrained by revenues from taxing and/or borrowing.
Therefore the purchase of a superannuation fund (in this case the Future Fund) in no way enhances the government’s ability to meet future obligations.
In fact, the entire concept of government pre-funding an unfunded liability in its currency of issue has no application whatsoever in the context of a flexible exchange rate and the modern monetary system.
The case of Norway, for example, is different. They are accumulating a sovereign fund because they are being flooded with external revenue from their North Sea energy assets.
They are running fiscal surpluses to ensure that the external revenue does not push the economy into an inflationary episode. At the same time the non-government sector enjoys first-class public services and infrastructure and can realise its overall saving targets without being compromised by the fiscal drag.
One might argue that the Norwegian fund is just an anti-inflationary device.
A more progressive Norwegian government might adopt the view that this surplus of income that the nation enjoys could be better diverted into foreign aid to help poorer nations achieve higher material standards of living rather than being use to buy ever increasing stocks of financial assets.
Ethical investment
Which leads to the final point.
I think the financial markets have the opportunity in the coming period to really change their entire mentality and become progressive leaders rather than parasitic takers.
It would be of great benefit if they channelled our net savings into ethical, green investments, perhaps taking a lower overall rate of financial return, as a trade-off for a massive positive social and environmental return.
Conclusion
I will report back after I have done a few of these workshops to let you know the reaction.
That is enough for today!
(c) Copyright 2019 William Mitchell. All Rights Reserved.
TOKYO – The once-obscure school of macroeconomic thought known as Modern Monetary Theory has been attracting a lot of attention lately. Some US progressives, such as Representative Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez (AOC), and economists like James K. Galbraith, now advocate including MMT in the policy conversation, while others, including Kenneth Rogoff, dismiss it as problematic and even dangerous.
Building on Abba Lerner’s theory of functional finance, MMT essentially argues that countries that issue their own currencies can never run out of money in the way private businesses can. For US progressives like AOC and presidential candidate Bernie Sanders, this implies that the Federal Reserve could print large amounts of money to fund initiatives with major long-term benefits, such as a “job guarantee” program or public infrastructure projects. Because the United States can borrow in its own currency, the logic goes, the surge in public-sector debt would not pose any real danger to the economy.
Some MMT advocates – including Stephanie Kelton, a former economic adviser to Sanders – point to Japan as proof that the approach works. Despite high public debt, its economy is steadily recovering, and standards of living are high.
Moreover, MMT advocates point out, Japan’s expansionary monetary policies – a central feature of Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s economic-revitalization strategy, Abenomics – have not generated a much-feared surge in inflation. Even within Japan, some argue that there is no need for a consumption-tax hike to fund public spending.
But there is a serious problem with this logic: Japan’s government is not as heavily indebted as is generally believed. Though Japan’s gross debt-to-GDP ratio, at 240%, is the highest in the developed world, what really matters – for the government, just like for private firms – is the net debt-to-GDP ratio, which accounts for real and financial assets. And Japan’s public companies have very large real assets.
In fact, by this measure, Japan is about on par with the US, and doing much better than France and Germany, according to the International Monetary Fund’s October 2018 Fiscal Monitor report, “Managing Public Wealth.” Further challenging Kelton’s assessment, Japan’s primary balance has improved under Abenomics, thanks to its economic recovery.
This does not mean that MMT has no merit, in Japan or elsewhere. In its campaign to increase consumption taxes, Japan’s Ministry of Finance drilled into the public psyche the concept of “Ricardian equivalence”: a government cannot stimulate consumer demand with debt-financed spending, because people assume that whatever is gained now will be offset by higher taxes due in the future. (It was this campaign that drove the MOF constantly to advertise the 240% figure.)
MMT can challenge this strict Ricardian belief, drawing attention to the potential of deficit financing, say, to boost employment through targeted social spending. And, indeed, Olivier Blanchard and Takeshi Tashiro have already proposed using limited deficit financing to help bring Japan’s interest rates up to zero, at a time when the government’s borrowing costs are low and the effectiveness of monetary policy is weak.
Implementing such a policy successfully, however, would demand careful attention to inflationary risks. The current deflationary phase will not last forever. Eventually, supply constraints will be reached, and inflation will return. If the government has been engaging in excessive deficit-financed spending, once inflation is triggered, it could quickly spin out of control.
MMT lacks any safeguard against that outcome (unlike, for example, the fiscal theory of the price level, which expressly counts on an independent central bank to manage inflation). In fact, supplying money with a constant nominal interest rate, as MMT seems to prescribe, would be the worst thing to do during an inflationary period, because the nominal market interest rate would probably be higher than the policy rate.
When discussing MMT, I cannot help but recall Goethe’s poem “The Sorcerer’s Apprentice.” The sorcerer leaves his apprentice alone to carry out his chores. Rather than perform his duties as expected, the apprentice decides to use the sorcerer’s magic, commanding a broom to carry buckets of water to fill a cauldron. It helps for a while, in fact, for quite a long time, but eventually the cauldron begins to overflow, flooding the room, and the apprentice cannot get the broom to stop adding more water. When he splits the broom with an axe, each piece becomes a new one, fetching water at twice the speed. Just short of catastrophe, the sorcerer returns and sets the situation right.
Policymakers who recklessly implement MMT may find, like the sorcerer’s apprentice, that once the policies are set in motion, they will be difficult to stop. And while a central bank can, with the requisite authority and independence, potentially step in to save the day, it is no all-powerful sorcerer.
Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019 http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019 http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019 http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019 http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
以下でMMTは魔法の弟子と揶揄されるがそもそも主流派経済学の弟子ではない Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. RajanJul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
浜田は英文の該当記事で魔法使いの弟子にMMTを論者を喩えている Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory? Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019 https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019 http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
返信削除以下でMMTは魔法の弟子と揶揄されるがそもそも主流派経済学の弟子ではない
Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory?
Raghuram G. RajanJul 1, 2019
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
(浜田宏一の文書ということになっているがインタビューを纏めたのは第三者だろう。
だからミッチェルも「シンジケート」と作者を呼称している。
ちなみに浜田宏一は現在MMTを支持している)
赤字容認理論、安倍首相に説明=浜田参与:時事ドットコム 2019/6/3
https://www.jiji.com/jc/article?k=2019060300943&g=pol
主流派経済学こそ制御できなくなった魔法だろう
MMTに魔術は含まれていない。そして弟子もいない。
追記すると、ミッチェルはマルクスからケインズへの影響関係を確定的に捉えているようだ
ミッチェル2019マクロではさらに共産党宣言の別の部分が引用されている
(M→C→M'、#26:422ではC-M-C'、さらにはM-C-P-C'-M'といった資本論の要点も紹介されている)
365 考える名無しさん[sage] 2019/07/03(水) 03:55:35.13 ID:0
返信削除マルクスの価値形態論は商品貨幣論及び金属主義の系譜だが
再生産表式は信用貨幣論を準備する
MMT(現代貨幣理論)の提唱者ミッチェルは最新ブログでマルクスを引用している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019
http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
《…このように強大な生産手段と交通手段とを魔法でよびだした近代ブルジョア社会は、
自分がよびだした地下の魔物を、もはや統御しきれなくなった魔法使に似ている。
この数十年来、工業と商業との歴史は、もはや、ブルジョアジーとその支配の生存
条件である近代的生産関係、所有関係にたいする、近代的生産力の反逆の歴史でしか
ない。これには、週期的にくりかえされるごとに、ますますはなはだしく、全ブルジョア
社会の存立をおびやかす商業恐慌をあげれば、十分である。》
(共産党宣言より)
http://redmole.m78.com/bunko/kisobunken/sengen1.html
ちなみにマルクスの使った魔法使いの比喩はゲーテ原作に由来している
ゲーテの原詩をデュカスが曲にし、さらにそれをディズニーが映画化したものが有名だ
魔法使いの弟子 "The Sorcerer's Apprentice"(ファンタジア 'Fantasia' Theme song)
https://youtu.be/b9dO-Yl-Oec
964 金持ち名無しさん、貧乏名無しさん (アウアウウー Sa47-q5pO)[] 2019/07/15(月) 12:27:48.00 ID:0gdD8xPta
返信削除>>856
内閣官房参与 浜田宏一 イェール大学教授が、現代金融理論(MMT)についてコメントしている。
https://www.financialpointer.com/jp/リカルドは憎いが・・・:浜田宏一教授/
浜田宏一教授
「MMTはこの厳格なリカーディアン的信仰に挑み、財政赤字による財政支出の可能性に目を向けさせ、
ターゲットを決めた社会的支出により雇用を促進することができる。
しかし、このような政策をうまく実行するには、インフレのリスクについて慎重な注意が要求される。」
「現在のデフレ局面は永遠に続くものではない。
最後には供給側の制約に達し、インフレが戻ってくる。
政府が過剰な財政赤字による財政支出を行えば、一たびインフレの引き金が引かれると、すぐに制御不能になってしまう。」
供給側の制約は、移民で回そうとする(現にしてる)から制約に達するのはかなり先になる
それまでデフレを甘受しろと言いたいのか?
そしてまた出た制御不能。ただの極論・暴論で財政民主主義の否定で憲法違反
結局、デフレ甘受して移民入れろとしか見えない。
856 金持ち名無しさん、貧乏名無しさん (ワッチョイ 17c9-TPoM)[sage] 2019/07/13(土) 14:35:47.40 ID:q5hN1U+H0
返信削除2019年7月20日号
http://dw.diamond.ne.jp/articles/-/27061
西井泰之(ダイヤモンド編集部)
世界を揺るがす「MMT」の真実
「反緊縮」を掲げて財政赤字を積極容認する「現代貨幣理論(MMT)」を巡る論争が熱を
帯びる。MMTは長期停滞を抜け出す突破口になるのか、それとも「異端の学説」にすぎな
いのか。アベノミクスの指南役の浜田宏一・イェール大学教授(内閣官房参与)に聞いた。
>有料。dマガジンで読める。冒頭はいちゃもんだが、結論はリフレMMT
浜田は英文の該当記事で魔法使いの弟子にMMTを論者を喩えている
返信削除Does Japan Vindicate Modern Monetary Theory?
Raghuram G. Rajan Jul 1, 2019
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/modern-monetary-theory-japan-inflation-by-koichi-hamada-2019-07
それに対しミッチェルは浜田の名は出さないで反論している
Why the financial markets are seeking an MMT understanding – Part 2 bill July 2, 2019
http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=42640
MMTは主流派という魔法使いの弟子ではないと言うのだ
ちなみにこの浜田が使った魔法使いの弟子という譬喩はゲーテの詩に基づき、マルクスが
共産党宣言で使用している
ミッチェルが引用したのは以下、
《…このように強大な生産手段と交通手段とを魔法でよびだした近代ブルジョア社会は、
自分がよびだした地下の魔物を、もはや統御しきれなくなった魔法使に似ている。
この数十年来、工業と商業との歴史は、もはや、ブルジョアジーとその支配の生存
条件である近代的生産関係、所有関係にたいする、近代的生産力の反逆の歴史でしか
ない。これには、週期的にくりかえされるごとに、ますますはなはだしく、全ブルジョア
社会の存立をおびやかす商業恐慌をあげれば、十分である。》
(共産党宣言より)
http://redmole.m78.com/bunko/kisobunken/sengen1.html
ちなみにマルクスの使った魔法使いの比喩はゲーテ原作に由来している
ゲーテの原詩をデュカスが曲にし、さらにそれをディズニーが映画化したものが有名だ
魔法使いの弟子 "The Sorcerer's Apprentice"(ファンタジア 'Fantasia' Theme song)
https://youtu.be/b9dO-Yl-Oec
FTPLは主流派から内在的批判として出てきた理論で実はMMTと近い
税が貨幣を価値付けているの考えているのだ
FTPLは期待効用を市場に任せるがMMTは利子率として政府が設定しうると考える
実体経済に直接働きかけ得るしそうすべきだと言うのだ
FTPLを盾に主流派は最後の悪あがきをしているがFTPLはほとんどMMTと合流する