水曜日, 6月 19, 2019

#28 IS-LM 3


#28 IS-LM 3




IS-LM Framework – Part 4


Previous Parts to this Chapter:

Chapter 16 – The IS-LM Framework

[PREVIOUS MATERIAL HERE IN PARTS 1, 2 and 3]

16.5 Policy analysis in IS-LM

The IS-LM framework is used within the mainstream approach to analyse the impact of fiscal and monetary policy changes on output (income) and interest rates, and by implication, employment.

Monetary policy is represented by the assumed capacity of the central bank to alter the money supply. Inherent in this appraoch is the view that central banks manipulate base money (reserves) which are then transmitted into a broader money supply via the money multiplier mechanisms.

In Chapter 9, we demonstrated how this view of central bank operations is not a valid representation of the real world and that, in fact, the central bank has little control over the money supply and conducts monetary policy principally via its capacity to set the short-term interest rate. However, for the purposes of this Chapter, to ensure we render the IS-LM approach faithfully, we assume the money supply is exogenous and under the control of the central bank.

Monetary policy changes are thus represented in the IS-LM framework by shifts in the LM curve.

Figure 16.2 showed that if the central bank increases the money supply, the interest rate falls at the current national income level. This is because at the existing interest rate, there is an excess supply of money and the interest rate has to fall to stimulate an increased demand for money.

The interest rate continues to fall until the demand for money is again equal to the increased money supply and money market equilibrium is restored.

In terms of the LM curve, this means that at higher levels of money supply, equilibrium interest rates will be lower at each income level which translates into a shift outwards in the LM curve. The opposite occurs when the money supply falls.

The LM curve shifts to the right when the money supply rises and shifts to the left when the money supply contracts.

Figure 16.7 shows the impacts of expansionary monetary policy. At some existing monetary policy stance captured by LM1 the equilibrium combination of the interest rate and national income is i*1, Y*1. Point A shows the equilibrium position where LM1 cuts the IS curve.

The central bank decides that the output gap (measured by the difference between the full employment national income level, YFE and the current national income level, Y*1) is intolerable (given the implied mass unemployment that would be associated with such a deficiency in output) and they increase the money supply.

The LM curve shifts to LM2, which drives down interest rates (to stimulate a higher demand for money). The new equilibrium is at Point B, with the equilibrium combination of the interest rate and national income at i*2, Y*2.

The rising income results from the positive impact on investment of the lower interest rates (represented by the movement along the IS curve from A to B). The more sensitive is investment spending to interest rate changes the more expansionary the monetary policy change will be.

Note, that in this case, monetary policy would not be able to achieve full employment because the economy would encounter a liquidity trap (at i0) before full employment was restored.

A contractionary monetary policy could be represented in Figure 16.7 by a shift in the LM curve from LM2 to LM1. This would drive interest rates up and national income down.

The falling income results from the negative impact on investment of the higher interest rates (represented by the movement along the IS curve from B to A). The more sensitive is investment spending to interest rate changes the more contractinoary the monetary policy change will be.

Figure 16.7 Expansionary Monetary Policy

Expansionary monetary policy drives the interest rate down and national income up. Contractionary monetary policy drives the interest rate up and national income down.

The extent of the expansion or contraction depends on the slope of the IS curve. The steeper the IS curve the less effective are monetary policy changes with respect to income changes.

Fiscal policy changes could be implemented by discretionary changes in government spending or the tax rate. We have learned that a rise in government spending shifts the IS curve to the right because for a given interest rate, the equilibrium level of national income rises when autonomous spending rises.

Similarly, a fall in government spending shifts the IS curve to the left because for a given interest rate, the equilibrium level of national income falls when autonomous spending falls.

The magnitude of the shift up or down in the IS resulting from a rise (fall) in autonomous spending is determined by the magnitude of the change in autonomous spending and the size of the expenditure multiplier.

For a given change in autonomous spending, the shift in the IS curve will be larger, the larger is the value of the expenditure multiplier.

The IS curve shifts to the right when government spending rises and shifts to the left when the government spending falls.

Figure 16.8 depicts an expansionary fiscal policy change (increase in government spending). At some existing fiscal policy stance captured by IS1 the equilibrium combination of the interest rate and national income is i*1, Y*1. Point A shows the equilibrium position where IS1 cuts the LM curve.

The treasury decides that the output gap (measured by the difference between the full employment national income level, YFE and the current national income level, Y*1) is intolerable (given the implied mass unemployment that would be associated with such a deficiency in output) and they increase government spending in order to stimulate aggregate demand.

The IS curve shifts to IS2 which creates a new equilibrium at Point B, with the equilibrium combination of the interest rate and national income at i*2, Y*2.

You will note that both the interest rate and national income are higher. The rising national income arises because at higher levels of aggregate demand, firms produce more output (and hire more workers).

How do we explain the higher interest rates? Within the IS-LM framework, the rising national income that follows the increased aggregate demand, increases the transactions demand for money. With the money supply fixed, the rising demand for money creates an excess demand for money at the original equilibrium interest rate (i*1) and rising interest rates motivate people to hold less cash. This is because the opportunity cost of holding wealth in the form of cash rises when interest rates rise.

You will note that if the interest rates had not have increased, the expansion in income would have been greater than the shift from Y*1 to Y*2.

Figure 16.8 Expansionary Fiscal Policy

The final change in aggregate demand is thus less than the initial ΔG. How do we explain this?

The rising interest rates impact negatively on private investment which offsets some of the increase in government spending. In the policy debates this impact is referred to as financial crowding out. The rising interest rates that follow the increase in government spending, crowd out other interest sensitive components of aggregate demand (in this case, private investment).

Note that fiscal policy could achieve full employment (at Point C) if the government kept increasing government spending such that the IS curve shifted to ISFE.

The extent of the financial crowding out depends on the slope of the LM curve. The steeper is the LM curve the less expansionary will fiscal policy be and the larger is the crowding out effects.

This is demonstrated in Figure 16.9. From an initial equilibrium at Point A, a fiscal stimulus (shifting IS curve to IS2) would increase national income to Y*2 and interest rate would rise to i*2 with the flatter LM curve (LM1) at the new equilibrium point, B1.

With a steeper LM curve (LM2), for the same fiscal stimulus (shifting IS curve to IS2), the new equilibrium point, B2 clearly involves a lower equilibrium income outcome and a higher equilibrium interest rate than occurred at Point B1.

The extent of the financial crowding out is higher with LM2 than LM1.

What explains this difference? The LM curve is steeper the more sensitive the demand for money (transactions and precautionary motives) is to national income changes and the less sensitive the speculative demand for money is to changes in interest rates.

Thus, small changes in national income lead to large changes in excess money demand at a given money supply level and the rise in interest rates to restore money market equilibrium, other things equal, has to be larger as a consequence. Additionally, for a given excess demand for money, the interest rate increase that is required to restore money market equilibrium is larger.

A extreme position is complete financial crowding out and this would occur if the LM curve was vertical. In this situation a given rise in government spending, for example, would be exactly offset by a decline in investment as the interest rate rose.

In that situation, fiscal policy would be totally ineffective

We should note that financial crowding out is not confined to fiscal policy changes exclusively. Any of the autonomous spending components, which can shift the IS curve and increase national income, trigger the money market mechanisms that see interest rates rise and interest-sensitive components of aggregate demand stifled.

Figure 16.9 Fiscal policy and financial crowding out

Note that the other extreme position would be a horizontal LM curve at some given interest rate. In this case there would be no financial crowding out and the fiscal stimulus to aggregate demand would be fully translated into changes in national income.

We will return to this extreme position when we discuss endogenous money theories later in the Chapter.

An expansionary fiscal policy change increases national income and interest rates.

The rise in national income is less than the change in government spending because the higher interest rates crowd out private investment.

The extent of the financial crowding out depends on the slope of the LM curve. The steeper is the LM curve the less expansionary will fiscal policy be and the larger is the crowding out effects.

There is complete crowding out when the LM curve is vertical and zero crowding out when the LM curve is horizontal.

16.6 Introducing the price level

Our derivation of the IS-LM framework initially assumed that the price level was fixed and all changes in output were real. This is consistent with the simple income-expenditure model developed in Chapter 12 where the focus was on the manner in which output and employment responds to changes in aggregate demand.

We assumed that firms were willing to supply whatever was demanded up to full capacity without changing their prices.

In this vein, we also treated the nominal and real interest rate has being interchangeable.

In this section we consider how changes in the price level impact on output and interest rates.

[TO BE CONTINUED IN PART 5]

Conclusion

PART 5 next week – Introducing the Price Level to the Analysis – PIGOU AND KEYNES EFFECTS AND CRITIQUE OF FRAMEWORK. 

Saturday Quiz

The Saturday Quiz will be back again tomorrow. It will be of an appropriate order of difficulty (-:

That is enough for today!

(c) Copyright 2013 Bill Mitchell. All Rights Reserved.



IS-LM Framework – Part 5

I am now using Friday’s blog space to provide draft versions of the Modern Monetary Theory textbook that I am writing with my colleague and friend Randy Wray. We expect to complete the text during 2013 (to be ready in draft form for second semester teaching). Comments are always welcome. Remember this is a textbook aimed at undergraduate students and so the writing will be different from my usual blog free-for-all. Note also that the text I post is just the work I am doing by way of the first draft so the material posted will not represent the complete text. Further it will change once the two of us have edited it.

Previous Parts to this Chapter:

Chapter 16 – The IS-LM Framework

[PREVIOUS MATERIAL HERE IN PARTS 1 to 4]

16.6 Introducing the price level

Our derivation of the IS-LM framework initially assumed that the price level was fixed and all changes in output were real. This is consistent with the simple income-expenditure model developed in Chapter 12 where the focus was on the manner in which output and employment responds to changes in aggregate demand.

We assumed that firms were willing to supply whatever was demanded up to full capacity without changing their prices. In this vein, we also treated the nominal and real interest rate has being interchangeable.

In this section we consider how changes in the price level impact on output and interest rates.

The price level is introduced into the IS-LM framework as an exogenous variable, that is, determined outside of the interest rate-income equilibrium defined by the intersection of the IS and LM curves. There are several complications involved in adopting this assumption, which we will abstract from for the sake of simplicity.

The income-expenditure model developed in Chapter 12, which underpins the derivation of the IS curve was defined in real terms. Thus, the expenditure components – consumption, investment, government spending and net exports – are all measured in constant prices.

We would expect the IS curve therefore to be invariant to changes in the general price level given that housholds, firms, government and the external sector have made decisions regarding real expenditures.

However, to date our analysis of the money market has fudged the question of the price level. The demand for money is a demand for real balances, motivated by the need to make transactions for the exchange of goods and services which we have just noted are defined in real terms.

But, the money supply is specified in nominal terms – an amount of dollars – and forms the unit in which all the other variables are accounted.

The real value of a given stock of money on issue, however, varies with the price level. For a given stock of dollars on issue, the real value is higher when the price level is lower, and, vice versa.

For example, assume that the money supply on issue is $1000 billion and the price index is 1. The real value of the money supply would be $1,000 billion.

Now if the price level rose by 5 per cent the price index would be 1.05 and the real value of the money supply would drop to $952.4 billion.

This means that users of the currency have less available in real terms to use for purchases and speculative holdings.

The same contraction in real value of the money supply could arise if the price level was unchanged (that is, the index remained at 1) and the nominal money supply fell to $952.4 billion.

In other words, the real value of the money supply can fall if the price level rises (for a given nominal money stock) or if the nominal money stock falls (for a given price level).

Alternatively, the real value of the money supply can rise if the price level falls (for a given nominal money stock) or if the nominal money stock rises (for a given price level).

Within the logic of the IS-LM framework, it is clear that if the price level rises and reduces the real value of the money supply, the interest rate will rise because at the previous equilibrium interest rate, there will now be a shortage of real balances relative to the demand for them.

The introduction of the general price level modifies our LM curve derivation. If a rising price level (with a constant nominal money stock) is equivalent in real terms to a declining nominal stock of money (at constant prices) then we can capture this impact via shifts in the LM curve.

The LM curve shifts to the left when the price level is higher, other things equal, and to the right when the price level is lower.

Figure 16.10 depicts two different LM curves at different price levels (P1 > P0).

The introduction of the price level now means that our interest rate-income equilibrium is now contingent on the price level. If there is a different price level, the equilibrium changes as noted.

This means that within this framework, the national economy equilibrium can shift without any change in monetary or fiscal policy if the price level changes.

Figure 16.10 IS-LM Equilibrium and the General Price Level

This observation was central to the debates between Keynes and the classical economists during the 1930s, which we examined in detail in Chapter 15.

Assume that the economy is currently at Point A, where the interest-rate is i1 and national income is Y*. The general price level is P1.

Point B is the full employment output level so that the current equilibrium is what Keynes would refer to as a underemployment equilibrium.
At Point A, the product and money markets are in equilibrium but there is an output gap and there would be mass unemployment in the labour market.

Keynes considered this to be the general case for a monetary economy and depicted the neo-classical model as a special case in which the equilibrium that emerged was also consistent with full employment. For Keynes, a monetary economy could be in equilibrium at any level of national income.

The neo-classical response to this was that unless we impose fixed wages on the model, the persistent mass unemployment would eventually lead to falling nominal wages and prices.

While this might not lead to a fall in the real wage (if nominal wages and prices fall proportionately), which would negate the traditional neo-classical route to full employment via marginal productivity theory, the fact remains that the lower price level increases real balances in the economy.

The reasoning that follows is that the reduction in prices leads to a decline in the transactions demand for money at every level of income because goods and services are now cheaper.

With the nominal stock of money fixed, the expansion of real balances combined with a decline in the demand for liquidity, results in a decline in the rate of interest.

As long as future expectations of returns are not affected adversely by the deflationary environment, the reduction in the rate of interest, stimulates investment spending, which leads to increased aggregate output and income via the multiplier effect.

As long as there is an output gap, deflation will continue and the interest rate will continue to fall until the economy is at full employment.

The link between real balances and the interest rate was referred to as the Keynes effect.

In terms of Figure 16.10, the LM curve shifts outwards as the price level falls and the rising investment is depicted as a movement along the IS curve. The new equilibrium is Point A.

This observation then led to neo-classical economists to consider the possibility of an underemployment equilibrium as a special case when wages and prices were fixed.

The view that Keynes’ underemployment equilibrium was a special case of the more general flexible price model became known as the Neo-classical synthesis. This approached recognised that aggregate demand drove income and employment (the so-called Keynesian contribution) but that the economy would tend to full employment if wages and prices were flexible (the Classical contribution).

There are several arguments against the view that a Keynes effect will be sufficient to generate full employment.

Keynes’ General Theory, – Chapter 19 – which is devoted to the impacts of money wage changes on aggregate demand.

Among other impacts, Keynes argued that lower money wages and prices will lead to a redistribution of real income (FIND PAGE NUMBERS):

(a) from wage-earners to other factors entering into marginal prime cost whose remuneration has not been reduced, and (b) from entrepreneurs to rentiers to whom a certain income fixed in terms of money has been guaranteed.

He concluded that the impact of “this redistribution on the propensity to consume for the community as a whole” would probably be more “adverse than favourable”.

Moreover, falling money wages will have a (FIND PAGE NUMBERS):

… depressing influence on entrepreneurs of their greater burden of debt may partly offset any cheerful reactions from the reduction of wages. Indeed if the fall of wages and prices goes far, the embarrassment of those entrepreneurs who are heavily indebted may soon reach the point of insolvency, — with severely adverse effects on investment.

Overall, Keynes concluded that there was “no ground for the belief that a flexible wage policy is capable of maintaining a state of continuous full employment”.

The debt-deflation argument was also recognised by other economists such as Irving Fisher in 1933, Michal Kalecki in 1944 and Hyman Minsky in 1982).

[TO BE CONTINUED IN PART 6]

Conclusion

PART 6 next week – CRITIQUE OF FRAMEWORK. 

Saturday Quiz

The Saturday Quiz will be back again tomorrow. It will be of an appropriate order of difficulty (-:

That is enough for today!

(c) Copyright 2013 Bill Mitchell. All Rights Reserved.