ジェームズ・デューゼンベリー(James Stemble Duesenberry、1918年7月18日 - 2009年10月5日)
歯止め(ラチェット)効果
ラチェット‐こうか〔‐カウクワ〕【ラチェット効果】
デジタル大辞泉の解説
《ラ
チェットは、歯止めの意》物価が上昇して実質的な購買力が低下したり、増税などで可処分所得が減少したりしても、貯蓄を取り崩すなどして、消費者がそれま
での消費水準をしばらくの間維持しようとすること。景気の底堅さを説明する理由の一つとされることが多い。歯止め効果。
『所得・貯蓄・消費者行為の理論』(現代経済学選書)
177頁
Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior, 1949年(『所得・貯蓄・消費者行為の理論』)
http://www.hetwebsite.net/het/profiles/duesenberry.htm
Duesenberry-Smithies Ratchet Effects
http://www.hetwebsite.net/het/essays/multacc/ratchet.htm
One may argue that the components of
Hicks's (1950)
growth cycle model, ceilings, floors and an exogenous rate of growth of autonomous
investment (equal to the rate of growth of factor supplies) is unsatisfactory. These
exogenous factors are, indeed, quite arbitrary and, as their values can be anywhere, there
does not seem to
essential cycles. A way to circumvent this is to appeal to
theories which obtain growth and cycles endogenously. Non-linear cycle models were
developed precisely for this purpose. However, the simplest alternative procedure to
obtain growth and cycles endogenously would be to modify the Hicks model with Duesenberry
"ratchet" effects on consumption and/or Smithies "ratchet" effects on
investment - more complicated non-linear models being left for later.
James
Duesenberry (1949) proposes
a consumption function which accounts for some adjustments for "habits" or
"standards of living". Conventionally, if income falls, then consumption should
fall proportionally with the marginal propensity to consume. Duesenberry rejected this:
once consumption habits are acquired, it is hard to get rid of them. Thus, income shocks
should have slightly different effects on consumption. Certain consumption habits are
formed at high income levels which are not completely abandoned when income falls. This
effect is captured in the following consumption function:
Ct = c0 + c1Yt-1 + c2Yt-1m
where Y
t-1m is the maximum level of income before
time period t. Thus, consumption habits acquired when income was at its highest influence
present consumption decisions.
Unlike Duesenberry, Arthur
Smithies's
(1957) "ratchet" effects are actually applied to the investment function rather
than to the consumption function and they also end up yielding cycles around a growth
trend. However, we shall stick mainly to the Duesenberry consumption function and omit the
Smithies ratchet - thus we presume the investment function has the same presumed to have
the same properties as before (now without depreciation) so:
It = I0egt + b
(Yt-1 - Yt-2)
thus, for goods market equilibrium:
Yt = c0 + I0egt + c1Yt-1
+ c2Yt-1m + b (Yt-1
- Yt-2)
or:
Yt - (c1 + b )Yt-1
+ b Yt-2 = (c0 + I0egt
+ c2Yt-1m)
which is our
old Hicksian second order linear
difference equation - only now with the term c
2Y
t-1m
involved among its autonomous components.
Without looking too carefully, one might suspect that the only effect
would be then that the particular numerical value of the equilibrium level of output would
be different. But in fact, the effect of adding a "ratchet" to consumption is
more substantial. Namely, we have changing parameters and changing steady-state
equilibria. This is easy to see. Suppose that Y
t-1m is far in the
past - call this case 1. In this case, then, the particular solution (equilibrium) to the
difference equation is:
Y1* = (c0 + I0egt + c2I0egt)/(1-c1)
where, assuming that c
1 = c (our old mpc), our characteristic
equation is now:
r2 - (c1 + b )r + b = 0
then we can just draw this as in the old Hicksian (
b
, c
1) space as in Figure 1 below. The only difference is that our curves are
now
b = (1 -
Ö (1-c
1))
2
and
b = (1 +
Ö (1-c
1))
2
where again monotonicity is defined when
b is above this and
oscillation when it is below and the border between stable and unstable dynamics remains
b = 1. Thus, nothing substantial changes except the numerical value
of the equilibrium.
But now suppose that an economy is growing. Then, in this case, call it
case 2, Y
t-1m = Y
t-1, i.e. last period's output
is
the maximum output. Thus, for case 2, the difference equation becomes:
Yt - (c1 + c2 + b
)Yt-1 + b Yt-2 = (c0 + I0egt)
so that the particular solution (equilibrium) is:
Y*2 = (c0 + I0egt)/(1-c1-c2)
which is different from that of case 1 as now c
2 enters in the
denominator as part of the multiplier. Similarly, under case 2, the characteristic
equation becomes:
r2 - (c1 + c2 + b
)r + b = 0
which is very different from case 1. It is easy to see that the curves for
the parameter constellations in (
b , c
1) space are
now:
b = (1 + Ö (1-c1
- c2))2
and:
b = (1 - Ö (1-c1
- c2))2
which are different from case 1. Thus, the boundaries we had before now
shift "in" as shown in Figure 1. When
b = 1,
now, c
1 = 1 - c
2 and not 1.
|
Figure 1 - Parameter Regions with Duesenberry Ratchet
Effects
|
What are the implications of this? Well, quite simply, the properties of
the parameters change during the cycle - thus one may consider it somewhat
"non-linear". Let us consider two cases: that of points P and Q in the figure
above. For the sake of simplicity, we shall assume henceforth that the exogenous rate of
growth for autonomous investment is zero, i.e. g = 0 so that I
0e
gt =
I
0. Thus, our equilibria Y
* are constant.
Suppose we have specific values of
b and c
1
(assumed constant) at point P. Then we alternate between explosive oscillations to
explosive monotonic dynamics. This is not altogether very interesting. The situation is
illustrated in Figure 2. Suppose we begin at a time when Y
t-1m is
max
1. Then, from t = 0 to t = T, the maximum is long in the past (max
1)
and our equilibrium is Y
1*. Under this, then, we have case 1 and
thus explosive oscillations. So, as we begin from time t = 0, Y has explosive
oscillations.
|
Figure 2 -Explosive Oscillations to Monotonicity
|
However, eventually, as the swings of Y are growing, we shall get a value
of Y which is greater than max
1. In our case, Y achieves and surpasses max
1
at t = T (or rather, just before that) in Figure 2. As a result, case 2 comes into effect.
Now, we have two things: firstly, a new, higher equilibrium (Y
2*)
will result and a new higher maximum will be established corresponding to the Y achieved
at t = T. However, as we now have explosive monotonic dynamics, then Y will
not
move down towards the new equilibrium Y
2*. Instead, it will continue
to explode upwards. But as it explodes, it will create a new higher maximum Y and thus a
new higher equilibrium Y
* after T. But the explosive monotonicity maintains
itself so again, the maximum continues to grow and Y
* continues to grow. This
is shown by the two lines Y* and max Y after t = T in the figure above.
The case of P, illustrated in Figure 2, is not that interesting for
we move from oscillations into monotonic explosions which eliminates the cycle. However,
suppose we were with a parameter constellation such as Q in Figure 1. Then,
both
before and after the parameter changes, we would
still have explosive oscillations.
This case is illustrated in Figure 3 below. We begin, again, at t = 0 with a maximum Y (=
max
1) and equilibrium Y
1*. We have explosive oscillations
and these continue until we hit t = T
1. Then, our upward swing of Y moves above
max
1 all the way to max
2. This becomes the new maximum and, as a
result, the new equilibrium is Y
2*. However, given that we still
have explosive oscillations, output falls after t = T
1 and, indeed, falls below
the new equilibrium. But, as we have explosive oscillations, then sometime in the next
upswing, at t = T
2, Y rises above max
2 all the way to max
3.
This creates a new maximum (max
3) and a new, higher equilibrium Y
3*.
Again, because we have oscillations, then from t = T
2 to t = T
3, the
rest of the cycle works itself through normally until, of course, during the upswing, at t
= T
3, again we surpass the old maximum to obtain a new maximum (max
4)
and a new higher equilibrium, Y
4*.
|
Figure 3 - Cycles and Growth
|
We can see now what is happening in Figure 3. The equilibrium Y
*
is rising stepwise and oscillations are happening around this equilibrium. Obviously,
then, we have
Harrod's grail of growth
with cycles:
Y
* increases while actual Y = Y
t is moving in cycles along this
increasing equilibrium. This is the result of parameter constellations such as Q when you
add
Duesenberry (1949) "ratchet"
effects on consumption on the simple
Hicksian
multiplier-accelerator model: cyclical growth without once the need for the Hicksian
paraphenelia of exogenous growth rates, ceilings or floors. If we had assumed a positive
exogenous growth rate (g > 0), then the equilibrium Y
* would be steeper
(i.e. the steps would have been greater) - perhaps to a point where the downswing would
result in only slightly or even no negative growth of output. Amplitudes of the cycles, of
course, should not be assumed constant but probably increasing over time.
0 Comments:
コメントを投稿
<< Home