http://www.freeassociations.org/
ブルス
社会主義における政治と経済
ユネスコ(UNESCO)主催の『資本論』一〇〇周年記念シンポジウムに提出された、現代経済分析にとってのマルクス再生産表式の重要性についての、彼のすぐれた論文には、とりわけ注目す(4)べきである。
社会主義経済成長論概要
著者
ミハイル・カレツキ 著[他]
出版者
日本評論社
出版年月日
1965
請求記号
331-cK14s-T
書誌ID(国立国会図書館オンラインへのリンク)
000001065017
国立国会図書館デジタルコレクション
言語(Language): トップへ このデータベースについて ヘルプ
すべて
詳細検索 インターネット公開 図書館送信資料 国立国会図書館内限定
社会主義経済成長論概要
目次・巻号
書誌情報
操作方法
目次・巻号
↓ 社会主義経済成長論概要 [83]
・ 目次
・ 序文
・ 第1章 定義と仮定/p1
・ 第2章 基本方程式/p11
・ 第3章 定率的発展/p19
・ 第4章 労働力予備が無限であるという条件のもとでの国民所得成長の加速化/p31
・ 第5章 労働力予備が制限されているという条件のもとでの国民所得成長の加速化/p43
・ 第6章 成長速度の制限要因としての貿易収支の均衡/p53
・ 第7章 資本集約度の引上げあるいは設備操業期間の短縮による労働生産性向上の加速化/p67
・ 第8章 完全就業のもとでの資本集約度引上げによる国民所得成長の加速化/p81
・ 第9章 完全就業のものでの設備操業期間の短縮による国民所得成長の加速化/p101
・ 第10章 外国貿易均衡の困難という条件のもとでの完全就業下の国民所得成長の加速化/p111
・ 第11章 無限の労働力予備があるばあいの資本集約度係数選択の問題/p117
・ 第12章 投資構造/p131
・ 訳者あとがき/p145
この資料は、著作権の保護期間中であるか、著作権の確認が済んでいない資料のためインターネット公開をしていません。閲覧を希望される場合は、国立国会図書館または図書館送信参加館へご来館ください。
>デジタル化資料のインターネット提供について
図書館送信参加館にご来館になる場合は、来館予定の図書館へ利用方法の確認をお願いいたします。
「書誌ID(国立国会図書館オンラインへのリンク) 」が表示されている資料は、遠隔複写サービスもご利用いただけます。
>図書館向けデジタル化資料送信サービス(図書館送信)について
>図書館送信参加館一覧
>遠隔複写サービス の申し込み方
国立国会図書館ホームサイトポリシー お問い合わせ
Copyright © 2011 National Diet Library. All Rights Reserved.
ブルス
カレツキのアプローチが完全無欠なものであるという印象をつくりだすのは、誤りであろう。たとえば、次のような点にかんしては、彼は批判されてよいであろう。すなわち、彼はその成長モデルでつねに所与の消費構造を前提としており、また、この点で選択の基準を定式化しようとする彼の唯一のこころみは、とうてい満足のゆくものとみなすことはできない。彼がひろく利用している生産曲線と、伝統的な新古典派の等量曲線とのあいだの関係は、不明瞭なままである。完全に外生的な変数としての技術進歩の扱いかたからは、若千の重要な経済的相互関係や社会的フィード・バックが脱け落ちている。しかしながら、全体としては、私は、カレツキのアプローチはもっとも実り多いもので、社会主義経済学にとって第一義的に重要な諸問題に、われわれの注意を集中させてくれた、と考えるものである。
ブルス
社会主義における政治と経済
カレツキが出発点として使用した基本的な成長モデルは、きわめて単純なものであった。国民所得の成長率(r)は、 一方では、労働生産性の成長率(α)と雇用の成長率(β)によって決定される。近似的な形で示すと、r=α十βである。同時に、 r は、国民所得に占める投資の割合(1/y=i)と限界資本・産出高比率(m、もしくは固定資本投資だけでなく在庫投資も考慮するときには、k)ならびに二つの追加的係数――すなわち、磨耗した旧型設備の廃棄のマイナス効果を反映するaと、既存生産能力利用の改善をあらわすu によって、決定される。投資と国民所得はいずれも、減価償却こみの総額である。こうして次の公式がえられる。
r=α十β (1)
r=1/k・i - a十u (2)
公式(2)は、産出高の増分単位あたりの在庫投資は全く不要であり、したがってk=mであるという、単純化した仮定に立って示されている。
r
| |/ 1/k
F|ーーーーーーーーーB|
| /|
| / |
|α+β / |
| / |
| / |
_____0|____/_____|_____
| / A1 i
u-a| /
| /
C|/
均斉成長の基本方程式
ブルス
社会主義における政治と経済
カレツキが出発点として使用した基本的な成長モデルは、きわめて単純なものであった。国民所得の成長率(r)は、 一方では、労働生産性の成長率(α)と雇用の成長率(β)によって決定される。近似的な形で示すと、r=α十βである。同時に、 r は、国民所得に占める投資の割合(1/y=i)と限界資本・産出高比率(m、もしくは固定資本投資だけでなく在庫投資も考慮するときには、k)ならびに二つの追加的係数――すなわち、磨耗した旧型設備の廃棄のマイナス効果を反映するaと、既存生産能力利用の改善をあらわすu によって、決定される。投資と国民所得はいずれも、減価償却こみの総額である。こうして次の公式がえられる。
r=α十β (1)
r=1/k・i - a十u (2)
公式(2)は、産出高の増分単位あたりの在庫投資は全く不要であり、したがってk=mであるという、単純化した仮定に立って示されている。
r
| |/ 1/k
F|ーーーーーーーーーB|
| /|
| / |
|α+β / |
| / |
| / |
_____0|____/_____|_____
| / A1 i
u-a| /
| /
C|/
均斉成長の基本方程式
…
カレツキの基本的成長モデルは、 ハロッド=ドーマー型モデルに類似しているが、あるいは同一であるとは、しばしば指摘されるところである。形式的にいえば、その通りであるかも知れないが、それに大した意味があるわけではない。なぜなら、こういった指摘は、実質的な解釈内容とこのモデルを使っての分析とを無視しているからである。このふたつは、冒頭の部分で論じた、社会主義経済学にたいする全般的アプローチと密接な関連がある。カレッキ自身は、すでにふれておいた「異なった社会体制における成長論」のなかで、 ハロッド=ドーマー型モデルは、次の理由から資本主義経済には適用不可能であると考えている。
「有効需要と資源利用の問題が、無視されている…‥。それが適用されるのは、有効需要の問題が実際に解決される、社会主義経済にたいしてである……。困難は、しかしながら、われわれが言及しているモデルは、しばしば、社会主義経済の現実に根ざす本質的な諸問題に集中されていないとぃぅ事実から、生ずる。」
彼はこうした問題として、二点を強調している。すなわち、(1)均斉的に拡張しつつある体制のいわゆる最適、均衡成長経路の探求に対立するものとしての、ひとつの成長経路から他の成長経路への移行の問題、(2)長期発展の隘路の問題が、それである。社会主義における成長論について書くさいの彼の努力は、主としてこの二つの問題と取り組むことにあった。
ブルス
カレツキ解説
p=(1+Cc)
| / 45度
| /
| /
| /
| /
A |_____/____ _ーB p/y
| / _ー |
A'|___/__ _ー___|B' (p/y)'
| / _ー _- ̄
| / _ー |_- ̄ |
|/_ー_- ̄|_____|______
C' C y
[AからA'への投資活動の低下]
p=(I+Cc):利潤は、投資(I)に資本家の消費(Cc)を加えたものに等しい
p/y:国民所得に占める所与の利潤の割合
資本主義(p/y)
社会主義(p/y)'
この例には多くの単純化がふくまれているが、本質的な点は正確である。ふたつの社会体制[注:資本主義(p/y)と社会主義(p/y)']では、「投資性向」の低下にたいする反応のしかたが異なるのである。一方は、賃金と利潤への所得分配の所与のパターンに産出高と雇用を適応させるという反応のしかたをし、他方は、産出と雇用の能力水準に所得分配を適応させるという反応のしかたをするのである。
Determination of Natonal Income …1971
…
マルクス再生産表式にかんしては
邦訳1958,47頁利潤の決定と国民所得の決定でカレツキ自身が触れている
この新評論社版は訳注54頁もある
《 いま考察している問題の理解のために,いくらか異なった視角から,上述
したところを示してみるのも無意義でないだろう.マルクスの「再生産表式」
にしたがって,全経済を3部門に分割するものとしよう。第Ⅰ部門は投資財
を生産し,第Ⅱ部門は資本家用消費財を生産し,第Ⅲ部門は労倒者用消費財
を生産する第Ⅲ部門の資本家は,労働者たちにその賃金相当額の消費財を
売却してもなお,みずからの利潤に等しい額の消費財の剰余部分を手許にの
こすだろう。これらの財は,第Ⅰ部門と第Ⅱ部門の労働者に売られるが,か
れらは貯蓄をしないから,それはかれらの所得に等しいだろう.かくして利
潤の総額は,第Ⅰ部門の利潤と第Ⅱ部門の利潤と,そしてこれら両部門の賃
金との総和に等しいであろう·すなわち,利潤の総額は両部門の生産物の価
値,換言すれば,投資財生産と資本家用消費財生産の価値に等しいだろう. (a)☆
もし,全部門にわたって利潤と賃金の間の分配がきまっていると,第Ⅰ部
門の生産と第Ⅱ部門の生産は第Ⅲ部門の生産をも決定するであろう.第Ⅲ部
門の生産費は, この部門の生産から得られる利潤が第Ⅰ部門と第Ⅱ部門の賃
金に等しくなる点まで拡張されるであろう,あるいは,別の表現をとれば,
第Ⅱ部門の雇用量と生産量は, この部門の生産量からこの部門の労働者が
の賃金で辟入する量を差し引いた残額を,第Ⅰ・第Ⅱ部門の賃金に等置する
点まで,拡張されるであろう.》
(47頁)
☆
《第3章の訳者注
(a)この関係をマルクス流に不変資本(ただし仮定により減価償却費部分のみ
からなり,原料費部分は含まない)cと可変資本化剰余価値mであらわす
とつぎのようになる.
第Ⅰ 部門=c1+v1+m1
第Ⅱ部門=c2+v2+m2
第Ⅲ部門 =c3+v3+m3
仮定により労働者の所得総計は労働者用消費財生産に等しいから
v1+v2+v3=c3+v3+m3 (i)
したがって,粗利潤の総計(純利潤プラス減価償却費)は第Ⅰ部門と第Ⅱ部門
の生産物の価値合計に等しくなる.
なせならば(i)式によって
v1+v2=c3+m3
だからである.》
(54頁)
It will be assumed, as Marx does, that the workers do not save. Moreover,
we shall disregard the problem of possible piling up of stocks of
unsold goods as only a passing phenomenon. It is then easy to arrive
at the fundamental Marxian " equation of exchange " between Departments
1 and 2 on the one hand and Department 3 on the other.
Profits in the latter, P3, are materialised in the wage goods which are
left to the capitalists of that department after payment of wages W3 which
absorb an equal amount of wage goods. Thus the wage-goods of the
value P3 are sold to the workers of Departments 1 and 2, that is :
(1) P3=W1+W2
Marx considers this equation in the context of expanded reproduction
proceeding at a given constant rate r. It is easy to see, however, that the
equation holds good under all circumstances as long as there is no piling
up of stocks of unsold goods, as mentioned above.
Considered in this general context equation (1) leads to a proposition
that - given the distribution of income between profits and wages in the
three departments - investment I and consumption of capitalists Ck determine
profits and the national income. Indeed, let us add PI + P2 to both
sides of equation ( 1 ). We obtain :
Hence :
(2) P=I+Ck
Moreover, if we denote Wl/Ⅰ , W2/Ck, W3/Cw by w1, w2, w3 respectively, we obtain
from equation ( 1 ) :(1-w3)Cw=w1Ⅰ+w2Ck
Consequently, we have for the consumption of wage goods :
(3) Cw=(w1Ⅰ+w2Ck)/(1-w3)
75
and for the national income :
(4) Y=Ⅰ+Ck+Cw=Ⅰ+Ck+(w1Ⅰ+w2Ck)/(1-w3)
Thus the national income (or product) Y which can be sold and the
profits P which can be realised are determined in all circumstances (and
not only in a state of uniformly expanding reproduction) by the level of
investment I and consumption of capitalists Ck (given the distribution
of income between wages and profits). A question may be raised as to
why equations (2) and (4) must be interpreted in this way and not the
other way around, i.e., that investment and consumption of capitalists
are determined by profits and national income. The answer to this rather
crucial query is as follows.
Investment and capitalists’ consumption in the short period considered
are the outcome of decisions taken in the past and thus should be
considered as given. With regard to investment, this follows directly
from the time-lag dependent on the period of construction. But changes
in capitalists’ consumption also follow those in profits with some delay.
Now, sales and profits in a given period cannot be a direct outcome of past
decisions : the capitalists can decide how much they will invest and consume
next year but they cannot decide how much they shall sell and profit. The
independent variables in a given period are investment and capitalists’
consumption. It is these magnitudes that through the equations (2) and
(4) determine the levels of national income and profits which can be realised.
The decisions of capitalists with regard to their investment and consum-
ption are made in " real " rather than in money terms, that is I and Ck should
be calculated in stable prices. If wl, w2, w3 are constant and money wage
rates in all three departments change in the same proportion, the same
is true in this case of prices of the produce of these departments. Moreover,
as is easy to see, equations (2) and (3) will hold also in "real" terms.
Any increase in "real" investment or capitalists’ consumption results
under these circumstances, in an increase in output of Department 3, Cw
to provide for a surplus of this department P3 sufficient to meet the demand
generated by the higher wage bills in Departments I and 2, i.e., W2 + W3.
However, such repercussions of an increase in I or Ck are obviously
possible only if there exist unused capacities in Department 3. Imagine
that such is not the case. Then Cw is fixed in real terms, i.e., is equal to a
constant B. In this case the increase in money value of W1 + W2 will
cause a rise in prices rather than in production of wage goods. The result
will be that the " value of W1, W2 and W3 will be reduced as compared
with the levels which would be achieved if unused capacities existed in
76
Department 3. Consequently w1= W1/I , w2 = W2/Ck, w3=W3/Cw=W3/B, where
all magnitudes involved are to be now interpreted in " real " terms, will
decline in the proportion reciprocal to the increase in the prices of wage
goods. Equation (3) can now be written in the form :
(w1I+w2Ck)/(I-w3)=B
When I and/or Ck decrease, w1, w2 and w3 decline in such a proportion
as to render the left hand side of the equation equal to B 1.
Sections II and III represent in fact the gist of the modern theory of
effective demand. As will be seen, this theory may be derived in full
from the Marxian equation (1) representing the exchange between Departments
1 and 2 on the one hand and Department 3 on the other, if this
equation is considered in the general context rather than in that of uniformly
expanding reproduction.
Let us now turn to the significance of the equations (2) and (4) just
in the latter context, i.e., in the process of a uniform accumulation of capital.
Let us denote the " real " stock of capital by K, the rate of net accumulation
by r and the rate of depreciation by δ. In this case we may write
the " equation of accumulation ", recalling that I is investment gross of
depreciation, in the form :
(5) I =(r+δ)K
Since we are considering the long-run process of growth, let us postulate
that capitalists’ consumption Ck is proportional to profits P. Since
according to formula (2) the latter are equal to I + Ck it follows that Ck
bears a constant relationship to I. We thus have :
Ck=mI
In consequence we may write equation (4) in the form :
(6) Y=(1+m)I+{I(w1+mw2)/(1−w3)}=I{1+m+(w1+mw2)/(1−w3)}
and substituting in it for I its value from equation (5) we obtain :
(7) Y=K(r+δ){1+m+(w1+mw2)/(1−w3)}
In a socialist economy prices of consumer goods are always fixed relative to wages
in such a way as to secure a full utilisation of the productive capacity B, i.e., the equation
(w1I)/(1−w3) = B is permanently fulfilled (Ck obviously equals 0 in this case).
77
The national income Y thus bears a constant relationship to the stock
of capital K (provided that w1, w2, w3 do not change (*2)). With a given
relationship of productive capacity to the stock of capital the degree of
utilisation of equipment is constant. Thus if capital equipment is
satisfactorily utilised in the initial position, this state of affairs is maintained
in the course of expanded reproduction and the problem of
effective demand does not arise.
It is this approach that is inherent in many contemporary theories
of economic growth. In particular if we differentiate the equation (7)
we obtain :
dY/dK=Y/K=rY/rK
Now, with a constant satisfactory utilisation of equipment, d Y is the
so-called capital-output ratio which we denote by R. Moreover, r K is
the net investment and thus rK/Y is the relative share of accumulation in
the national income which we shall denote by a. We thus have :
1/R=r/a
or r=a/R
which is the basic formula of the Harrod-Domar theory (in which, however,
the coefficient a represents the " propensity to save of the population "
rather than the ratio of net accumulation out of profits to the national income
which depends on its distribution between capitalists and workers).
In fact many of the contemporary theories of growth are simply
variations on the theme of Marxian schemes of expanded reproduction
which are represented in this paper by equations :
(1) W1+W2=P3
and
(5) I=(r+σ)K
The repercussions of changes in investment and capitalists’ consumption
described in section II do not raise, I believe, any major misgivings.
In contrast to this, the moving equilibrium described in section III depends
on the very far-reaching assumption that capitalists are willing to engage
*2. If the productive capacities of all three departments expand at the same rater
the shortage of wage-goods discussed in the preceding section will not come into the picture.
78
in investment which increases their capital at a constant rate r per annum.
What happens, however, if having become more cautious (perhaps under
the influence of a change in the social structure of their class) they decide
to reduce investment from (r + δ) K to (r' + δ) K where r’< r?
It follows directly from formula (7) that Y/K and thus the degree of utilisa-
tion of equipment declines in the proportion (r'+δ)/(r+δ) as a result of the decline
of effective demand. It is clear that in this situation the " cautious " capitalists
will not be any more agreeable to a lower rate of accumulation r’
but will reduce it further to r " < r’, and this will in turn affect correspondingly
the degree of utilisation of equipment.
Some economists tend to consider this phenomenon as a down-swing
phase of the business cycle which takes place around the initial path of
growth. However, such a proposition is not well founded : there is no
reason why having left the initial unstable path, investment must fluctuate
around it rather than around the depreciation level δK. Or to put it in
Marxian terms : why cannot a capitalist system, once it has deviated downwards
from the path of expanded reproduction, find itself in a position of
a long-run simple reproduction ?
In fact we are absolutely in the dark concerning what will actually
happen in such a situation as long as we have not solved the problem of
determinants of investment decisions. Marx did not develop such a theory
but nor has this been accomplished in modern economics. Some attempts
have been made in the development of the theory of cyclical fluctuations.
However, the problems of the determination of investment decisions involving
the elements associated with the long-run trend are much more difhcult
than in the case of the "pure business cycle " (i.e., in a system which
in the long run is subject to simple reproduction). I myself tried to do
something along these lines but I consider my work in this field to be definitely
of a pioneer nature (*3). One thing, however, is clear to me : the longrun
growth of the national income involving satisfactory utilisation of
equipment in a capitalist economy is far from obvious.
That Marx was deeply conscious of the impact of effective demand
upon the dynamics of the capitalist system follows clearly from this passage
of the third volume of the Capital : "The conditions of direct exploitation
and those of the realisation of surplus-value are not identical. They
are separated not only by time and space but logically as well. The former
*3. A new paper of mine on the subject appeared in the June issue of the Economic
journal.
79
are limited merely by the productive capacity of the society, the latter by
the proportions of various branches of production and by consumer power
of the society ".
However, he did not systematically scrutinise the process described
by his reproduction schemes from the point of view of the contradictions
inherent in capitalism as a result of the problem of effective demand.
It is one of his most prominent followers, Rosa Luxemburg, who expressed
very definite and even extreme views on the subject : she rejected altogether
the possibility of long-run expanded reproduction if no " external
markets " are in existence. By ”external markets ” she understood
those outside the world capitalist system consisting not only of underdeveloped
countries but also of the non-capitalist sectors of developed capitalist
economies, for instance, peasant agriculture as well as government purchases.
Her argument suffers from the fact that she considers investment
decisions as being made by the capitalist class as a whole and this class is
frustrated by the knowledge that finally there is no market for the economic
surplus. However, her scepticism as to the possibility of long-run expanded
reproduction is valuable because the self-propelled growth of capitalist
economy cannot, indeed, be taken for granted. If this economy expands
at all without the assistance of "external markets" , this, to my mind, is
due to certain aspects of technical progress which, however, do not necessarily
assure a satisfactory long-run utilisation of equipment.
Nor should the significance of ”external markets ”in the development
of capitalism be disregarded. In particular, in present-day capitalism
the " external markets " in the form of government expenditure,
especially on armaments, play an important role in the functioning of capitalist
economies. This expenditure to the extent that it is financed by
loans, or even by taxation of capitalists, contributes to the solution of the
problem of effective demand because its effect is not offset by the decline
in investment and consumption. (The latter would be the case if this
expenditure were financed by indirect or direct taxation of workers.) Thus
today the ”external markets ” in this particular form are even of greater
significance for expanded reproduction than at the time when Rosa Luxemburg
propounded her theory.
The high degree of utilisation of resources resulting in fact from these
government-made”external markets ”has a paradoxical impact upon Western
economic theory. It creates an atmosphere favourable to the construction
of models for the growth of ” laissez faire ” capitalist economies
unperturbed by the long-run problem of effective demand.
____________
Michal Kalecki is Professor of Economics at the Central School of Planning and Statistics
in Warsaw, and a member of the Polish Academy of Science. Among his major
works a:re Essay on the theory of the business cycle (1933)( in Polish); Theory of
economic dynamics (1954); Outline of the theory of growth in a socialist economy
(1963) (in Polish); " Trend and business cycles reconsidered ", Economic journal,
June 1968.
The Marxian equations of reproduction and modern economics
http://ssi.sagepub.com/
Social Science Information
http://ssi.sagepub.com/content/7/6/73.citation
The online version of this article can be found at:
DOI: 10.1177/053901846800700609
Social Science Information 1968 7: 73
Michal Kalecki
The Marxian equations of reproduction and modern economics
Published by:
http://www.sagepublications.com
On behalf of:
Maison des Sciences de l'Homme
Additional services and information for Social Science Information can be found at:
Email Alerts: http://ssi.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts
Subscriptions: http://ssi.sagepub.com/subscriptions
Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav
Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
What is This?
>> Version of Record - Dec 1, 1968