http://www.freeassociations.org/
岩波『図書』連載「思想の散策」2015/09
VALUE THEORY AND BUSINESS CYCLES
ond, labor being used less would be able to buy back less, hence
demand would drop off. (To this extent Marx departed from
an embodied labor theory to that of demand and supply. In
fact, embodied value theorists unwittingly pass over to a demand
and supply analysis with more or less frequency.)
THE BUSINESS CYCLE AND SURPLUS VALUE
Clearly for Marx, the secular trend was downward. But in
addition to a secular trend, he sought also to establish the fact
of a constantly recurring business cycle. The theory of the
cycle or of crises was based wholly upon his Surplus Value
analysis. Surplus Value holds so important a place in the general
theory of Marx that it is necessarv to study it with care.
In dealing with exchange or the metamorphosis of commodities, he first treated C-M-C [Commodity for Money for Commodity]. Such an exchange he considered no different in principle from that of barter since the object of exchange was to
transfer a commoditv of little or no utility to its possessor for
a different commodity of high utility, and money entered as a
convenient medium to effect the transaction. This double transaction indicated no exploitation, for the assumption was that in
each transaction there was an exchange of equivalent values, or
quantities of embodied labor, so the final commodity had
neither more nor less value than the original commodity, but
had a higher utility for the recipient. Thus the metamorphosis
C-M-C represented an exchange of equivalent values and no
exploitation. Marx admitted the possibility of variation in value,
but such would be accidental and negligible and not inherent in
the process.
But the metamorphosis M-C-M' was fundamentallv different. And it was in explaining this formula that Marx treated
thoroughly the nature and source of surplus value. In this case
the individual starts with money and ends with money. The only
possible motive, then, for making the two exchanges was to end
with more money than at the beginning. And the extent to which
the second M or M' exceeds the first, is the measure of surplus value.
47:
However, surplus value was not created or gained in
the circulation of commodities but in production. The first M
represented the money paid to labor for wages. In return for
the wages received labor created commodities C which belonged
to the employer, the value being determined by the amount of
labor-time or social labor-power incorporated. Then Marx, in
the inimitable Marxian style, proceeded to show that, whereas
there was an exchange of equivalents as between commodities,
vet with the concentration of capital and tools into the hands
of capitalists and the rise of the proletariat, divorced from tools
and compelled to seek employment of the capitalist, there arose
a transaction between employer and laborer, a transaction in
volving the exchange of labor-power for subsistence, in which
case there was no guarantee whatsoever that there would be an
exchange of equivalents, but rather a predetermined certainty
that labor would invest more social labor-power than would be
returned as wages
Marx then turned directly to an analysis of the determination of wages. "We must now examine more closely this peculiar commodity, labor-power. Like all others, it has its value.
How is that value determined?"
Value of Labor-Power Determined by Cost of Subsistence
and Perpetuation
"The value of labor-power is determined as in the case of every
other commodity by the labor-time necessary for the production, and
also for the reproduction of this special article. So far as it has value,
it represents no more than a definite quantity of the average labor
of society incorporated in it. Labor-power exists only as a capacity, or
power of the living individual. Its production, consequently, presup-
poses his existence. Given the individual, the production of labor-
power consists in his reproduction of himself or his maintenance. For
his maintenance he required a given quantity of the means of subsistence. Therefore the labor-time requisite for the production of
labor-power reduces itself to that necessarv for the production of those
means of subsistence; in other words the value of labor-power is the
value of the means of subsistence necessary for the maintenance of the
laborer. .. . His means of subsistence must therefore be sufficient
to maintain him in his normal state as a laboring individual.
48:
His natural wants such as food, clothing, fuel and housing vary according
to the climatic, and other physical conditions of his country. On the
other hand the number and extent of his so-called necessary wants, as
also the modes of satisfying them, are themselves the product of his-
torical development, and depend therefore to a great extent on the
degree of civilization of a country, more particularly on the condi-
tion under which, and consequently on the habits and degree of com
fort in which, the class of free laborers has been formed. In contra-
distinction therefore to the case of other commodities, there enters
into the determination of the value of labor-power a historical and
moral element. Nevertheless in a given country at a given period the
average quantity of the means of subsistence necessary for the laborer
is practically known. .
into the value of a definite quantity of the means of subsistence. It
therefore varies with the value of the means or with the quantity of
labor requisite for their production." 6
The value of labor-power resolves itself
Thus we are led to see that Marx held that the wages of labor
were determined, not by the amount of social labor-power which
they invested in commodities for their employers, but by the cost
of maintenance which tended to hover around the subsistence
level, though it might be modified upwards slightly by the pre-
vailing standard of living. It was by showing that labor actually
did embodv more labor-power in the commoditv which it cre-
ated for emplovers than was embodied in the monev which it
received as wages that employers found themselves the pos-
sessors of commodities more valuable than their cost. This rep-
resented surplus value created bv labor, for 'which it received no
equivalent.
Returning to a final analysis of the formula M-C-M' the employer possessed a certain quantity of money, which represented
so much embodied or crystallized social labor-power. With this
he employed workmen who, in exchange, created for him the C
of the equation or so many commodities in which was embodied
a quantity of social labor-power, which, as we have already observed, might hold little or no relation to the value of money
which he gave for its production and tended on the average to be far in excess.
6 Marx, Capital, Vol. I, pp. 189-91
49:
This C of the equation was then sold on the
market at its full value in exchange for a quantity of money of
exactly equivalent value, i.e., embodying the same amount of
crvstallized social labor-power. By the extent to which the
quantity and value of the second M exceeded that of the first, by
so much had surplus value been created by labor. It also represented the exact extent to which labor had been exploited.
As has been said, the wages of labor were determined, by
the cost of subsistence, or of production and reproduction. The
employer therefore paid him a sufficient money wage to guaran-
tee that subsistence. But upon payment of that wage, the capital
ist laid claim to the full productive capacity of the worker. To
illustrate mathematicallv, if labor in six hours embodied value
in commodities equivalent to that contained in the specie re-
ceived as wages, but the employer withheld the specie until an
additional six hours of labor-power had been embodied, then it
is clear that labor has created six hours of surplus value for the
employer for which no equivalent was paid. This represented
accurately the degree of exploitation of labor, and Marx called
it "surplus value."7
But exploitation has its limits and cannot go on indefinitely
without producing serious maladjustments in the commodity
field. All commodities produced must be exchanged (or vir-
tually all in modern capitalistic economy) and the only effective
demand is the supply of another commodity, the value of which
is proportionate to the labor-power embodied. But the greatest
group of buyers, or consumers is comprised of the laboring class
which has been "robbed" of part of its purchasing power, hence
it cannot buy back the product of its labor. Commodities seek a
market but can find none, or if they do, they must seek it at a
market price much below the actual or market value. Then both
entrepreneurs and labor lose, the former becomes bankrupt and
the latter unemploved because factories close down and the world
experiences a crisis. Indeed it comes at the time when the supply
of commodities is the greatest. While the occasion for the crisis
7 Marx, Capital, Vol. I, pp. 197-215
was bankruptcy of entrepreneurs, the basic cause was in the ex-
ploitation of labor through employers' extortion of surplus value.
If the cause of crises was to be found in underpavment of
workers, with consequent lack of market for goods, a glut of the
market and bankruptcy of employers, how was recovery to come
about? The crisis was caused by too much goods, not only con-
sumption goods, but also capital goods; in other words the
powers of production had outrun the power of effective demand
or consumption, and a bottomed market resulted.
But all above the dire poverty line kept on consuming fairly
normally even in time of depression. Ultimately the glut was
worked off, because factories were closed down and production
had ceased. Also, many bankrupt firms were unable to start
again, machinery rusted away, factories were abandoned, etc. In
other words the function of depression was to scrap enough
capital goods so that the powers of production no longer ex-
ceeded those of consumption, ie.) consumption goods became
scarce, market price came back to market value, which always
contained a margin of profit, hence industries started up with a
vim and the cycle started on its first phase again, but only to
run the gamut of the previous cycle
Thus about the downward secular trend, there ran constantly
this cyclical curve of prosperity, glut, bankruptcy, crisis, and
depression; all based in the last analysis on "surplus value ex-
ploitation.'"
Thus far, we have attempted to show how Marx explained
the secular trend of the price level on the basis of embodied
value, and the cyclical movement of market prices on the basis
of surplus value. Standing alone each explanation seems logical
and complete. The difficulty arises when we attempt to reconcile
the two. If the value of commodities was determined bv the
amount of labor embodied, how could goods sell at times far
below this value, as at the time of crisis, and at other times far
above their value as in the period of prosperity?
Marx noted the apparent contradiction and promised a recon-
ciliation at a later time.
51:
This was eagerly looked for in the second
volume of "Das Kapital" but strangely, it was conspicuous by its
absence. However, before his death the attempt had been made
and Engels found it among his manuscripts, and published it in
Volume III.8
Stripped of its verbiage, numerous definitions and involved
formulae, Marx held that two sets of forces were operating in
the determination of value and market price. The fundamental
and primary force, was embodied social labor-power. This de-
termined the value of all commodities. (Value here is used in ex-
actly the same way in which Ricardo used "Natural Value.") The
natural value of commodities was determined by the quantitv of
labor embodied, and market price would never depart from this
unless influenced by some disturbing factor. The disturbing factor
was found in "Demand and Supply" which constituted a secondary
force. But demand and supply had no effect so long as they were in
equilibrium. Furthermore, demand would always equal supply
if labor were not exploited. If it could buy back the full volume
of its product the market would never become glutted and
therefore market price would be held constantly at the natural
value. But due to the exploitation of labor, the compulsory pro-
duction of surplus value, supply exceeded demand and when de-
mand and supply were not in equilibrium, they did have an effect
upon prices and compelled market price to depart from the curve
of Natural Value.
In the words of Marx:
"If demand and supply balance, then they cease to have any effect,
and for this very reason commodities are sold at their market values.
If two forces exert themselves equally in opposite directions, they
balance one another, they have no influence at all on the outside,
and any phenomena taking place at the same time must be explained
by other causes than the influence of these forces. If demand and sup
ply balance one another, they cease to explain anything, they do not
affect market values and therefore leave us .. . in the dark. . . .
It is evident that the essential fundamental laws of production can-
not be explained by the interaction of supply and demand. . . . For
these laws cannot be observed in their pure state until the effects of
8 See Marx, Capital, Vol. III, Ch. X
です
4)式と
式を整理すると、
どちらも
2
となりますが、これが「拡大再生産」の条件です。すなわち、第Ⅱ部門の不変資本は、
1部門の可変資本と剰余価値の合計よりも小でなければならないのです
,マルクスの剰余価値論
第
《経済学史の講義でマルクス経済学を教えるとき、初心者には退屈な「唯物史観」や「疎
外された労働」などよりは、第二巻の「再生産表式」から教えてみるのも一つの方法では
ないでしょうか。そこから、第1巻に立ち戻ると、労働生産力の発展を図るには、剰余価
値を資本に再転化するという意味での「資本の蓄積」がおこなわれなければならないとい
う件にぶつかりますが、これが「再生産表式」でいう「拡大再生産」であることはすぐに
わかります。》
入門経済学の歴史ちくま新書根井雅弘 2010
38~9頁
入門経済学の歴史 | |
叢書名 | ちくま新書 ≪再検索≫ |
著者名等 | 根井雅弘/著 ≪再検索≫ |
著者等紹介 | 1962年宮崎県生まれ。早稲田大学政治経済学部卒。京都大学大学院経済学研究科博士 課程修了。現在、京都大学大学院経済学研究科教授。専門は現代経済思想史。著書に「経 済学はこう考える」など。 |
出版者 | 筑摩書房 |
出版年 | 2010.4 |
大きさ等 | 18cm 250p |
NDC分類 | 331.2 |
件名 | 経済学-歴史 ≪再検索≫ |
要旨 | 経済システムを貫く客観的法則をはじめて見出したケネー。国民を豊かにするために何が 必要かを徹底的に考え抜いたスミス。こうした経済学の草創期からリカード、マルクス、 ワルラスらを経てケインズ、シュンペーター、ガルブレイス、そしてフリードマンやマン キューなど現代の経済理論に至るまでを平明に解説。重要トピックごとに学説史を再構成 することで、それぞれの経済学者が提示した理論間のつながり・対立点が鮮やかに浮き彫 りになる。第一人者による入門書の決定版。 |
目次 | プロローグ 経済学史の全体像をおさえる;第1章 経済循環の発見;第2章 価値と分 配の理論;第3章 ケインズ革命;第4章 多様なケインジアン;第5章 制度主義の展 開 |
内容 | 経済学の巨人たちは時代の課題とどう向き合い、思想を構築したのか。主要テーマ別に学 説史を描くことで読者の有機的な理解を促進。経済学者たちが提示した理論間のつながり ・対立点を浮き彫りにする。 |
039
第一章
経済循環の発
ears学史の講義でマルクス経済学を教えるとき、初心者には退屈な1唯牧リ包
外された労働」な
第二巻の「再生産表式」から教えてみるのも一つの方法では
第1巻に立ち戻ると、労働生産力の発展を図るには、剰余価
とよりは、
"
くだり
生産手段が私有されている「資本主義」の下では、資本家は「労働力」という商品を購
入しますが、資本家の目的は、資本としての貨幣を増殖させることにあります。マルクス
は、これをG-WIGとして簡潔に表現しました(ここで、Gは貨幣, Wは商品, G'= G+
△Gはより多くの貨幣を意味しています。英語の文献では、MIC-1と表現されることが多い
でしょう)。
留意すべきは、商品としての労働力が、他の商品と同じように価値法則に従って交換さ
れる(すなわち,その価値は、労働力を再生産するのに必要な労働時間によって決定される)と
いうことです。しかし、労働力をその価値どおりに手に入れた資本家は、その労働を自由
に処分することができるので、ここに「剰余価値」が生み出される鍵が隠されることにな
ります。
見
具体的な例を挙げると、いま、一日の労働時間が111時間だとして、そのうち労働力の
価値の再生産のために必要な労働時間(「必要労働時間」)は六時間だとしましょう。とす
オー!!マイ神様!! 2018年2月19日 180219 実は空海は人に好かれる天才だった時の最高権力者を夢中にさせた知られざる方法とは空海が残...
(Adobe PDF)
-htmlで見る 太田拓男
Ted Bergstrom - “Ethics, evolution, and neighborly games”
マルクスの間違いは相対的であるはずの貨幣を
歴史的に位置付けるなかで絶対的とした点だ
これはマルクスを読む側のヘーゲル的バイアスでもある
ヘーゲルとマルクスは違うが
それはマルクスが唯物論だから違うのではない
マルクスのテクストは弁証法で掬い取れない夾雑物をもつ
ただしカントのカテゴリー論、アンチノミー論と並べると見えてくるものがある
http://nam-students.blogspot.jp/2016/10/blog-post_9.html
http://econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/eep/manmaker2.pdf
均衡において実現する結果が、果たして経済全体の厚生(富や豊かさ)を最大にするのかを分析するのが厚生分析である。ミクロ経済学では、この厚生分析にはパレート効率性という基準を用いる。ここで、パレート効率的であるとは、相手の利得を減らさないでは自分の利得を増やすことのできない状態をいう。これが、日常語での効率性、すなわち、「無駄がないこと」と同義であることは、次のように考えてみればわかる。いま資源を2人で無駄なく分け合っているとする。このとき、二方のプレーヤーが自分の取り分を増やそうと思えば、相手の取り分を奪うしかない6この状況は、まさに先ほど述べたパレート効率性の基準にかなっている。逆に、相手の利得を下げないでも自分の利得を上げられる場合、パレート効率的ではない。一般に、各プレーヤーの利得の和を最大にする結果がパレート効率的になる。もちろん、パレート効率性以外にも厚生を測る尺度はいろいると提案されている。たとえば、有名なものにマキシミン基準がある。マキシミン基準では、実現可能な各配分について、最も効用(あるいは利潤)が低い主体に着目する。そのうえで、この最低レベルにいる主体の効用水準(あるいは利潤)力S最も高くなるような配分を社会全体では採用すべきだとするものである。たとえば、経済には3人の主体がいて、実現可能な配分がスyの2つだとする。それぞれの配分において各主体が享受する効用水準をそれぞれχ=(60,90,120)、y=(150,30,120)とする。配分χで最低レベルの効用水準は60であり、配分yで最低レベルの効用水準は30なので、マキシミン基準では配分Xを選ぶことになる。一方、3人の効用の和が最大になるのは配分yなので、パレート効率性の基準では配分yを選ぶことになる。ミクロ経済学では、市場取引における均衡分析がその中心的な課題である。では、なぜ人は市場で取引を行うのだろうか。これについては、古典派経済学者デビッド・リカードが、なぜ国々の間で貿易が行われるかを説明した比較生産費説について考えてみるのがよい。